Budget Projections, Federal Debt, Social Security, and
Medicare
George H. Blackford © 1/31/2014
The
Congressional Budget Office (CBO) publishes an annual report that
provides projections of the federal budget under
two
scenarios: an extended baseline scenario and an extended
alternative fiscal scenario. According to the CBO:
The extended baseline scenario generally adheres
closely to current law. . . .
Under . . . the extended alternative fiscal
scenario, certain policies that are now in place but that are scheduled to
change under current law would continue instead, and some provisions of
current law that might be difficult to sustain for a long period would be
modified. . . .
The 2013 Long-Term Budget Outlook.
In effect, the baseline scenario is designed to
examine the implications of current law on the federal budget over time, and
the alternative fiscal scenario is designed to examine the implications of
past and current policies and practices on the federal budget over time.[1]
It is the purpose of this
note to show that when we examine our fiscal problems within the framework
of the past and current policies and practices embodied in the CBO's alternative fiscal scenario
we are driven to two inescapable conclusions.
The first is that unless we increase taxes it is going to be impossible to
stabilize the federal debt to GDP ratio and, at the same time, maintain
Social Security and Medicare without dramatic cuts in the benefits of these
programs in the future.
The second is that even
if we do increase taxes it is going to be impossible to stabilize the debt
ratio and maintain the benefits of Medicare without controlling the rising cost of healthcare in the private sector of the economy. It is further argued that, ultimately, this means we must
find a way to implement some kind of
single-payer,
universal healthcare system if Medicare is to survive.
The Federal Debt Problem
The fundamental
nature of the federal debt problem is shown in Figure 1 where the actual levels of federal spending, revenues, and surpluses as a
percent of GDP are plotted from 1901 through 2012 and the CBO's 2013 alternative fiscal
scenario projections of these ratios are plotted from 2013 through 2038. The table
below the graphs summarizes the changes in the CBO's projected values over
the projection period.
Figure 1: Government Spending, Revenues, Deficits,
and Debt Projections
from the CBO's 2013 Alternative Fiscal Scenario, 1901-2038.
(Percent of GDP) |
2013 |
2038 |
Difference |
% Change |
Debt to GDP Ratio |
73% |
158% |
85.0% |
116.4% |
Revenues |
17.0% |
18.1% |
1.1% |
6.5% |
Total Spending |
20.9% |
31.7% |
10.8% |
51.7% |
Revenues Minus Total Spending |
-3.9% |
-13.6% |
-9.7% |
248.7% |
Net Interest |
1.3% |
7.5% |
6.2% |
476.9% |
Non-Interest Spending |
19.6% |
24.2% |
4.6% |
23.5% |
Source:
The 2013 Long-Term Budget
Outlook (Supplementary
Data),
Office of
Management and Budget (Table
1.2).
When we look at the projections in Figure 1 we find that under
the policies assumed by the CBO in its alternative fiscal scenario,
Revenues are projected to increase only 1.1% of GDP from 2013 through
2038 while
Total
Spending is projected to increase by 11% of GDP over that same period.
These revenue and expenditure patterns are accompanied
by an increase in the deficit (negative surplus) from 3.9% to 13.6% of
GDP. These deficits must be financed, and the way they are financed is
through borrowing. This, of course, increases the federal debt.
As can be seen in Figure 1, rising debt does
not always lead to a problem. When GDP is increasing faster than the
debt, as it did for most of 1950 through 1974, the ratio of debt to GDP falls.
In this situation, the debt becomes less of a burden as the increase in debt
is less than the increase in the tax base (GDP) needed to service the debt.
The problem arises when the debt increases faster than GDP, as it is
projected to do in Figure 1 from 2017
onward.
A continual increase in debt relative to GDP is
unsustainable in that it will eventually lead to a situation in which
interest payments overwhelm the budget. This problem is indicated in
Figure 1 by the projected 6.2 percentage point increase Net Interest
from 2013 through 2038 as the share of Total Spending devoted to
Net-Interest increases from 6.2% (0.0622=1.3/20.9) in 2013 to 23.7%
(0.2366=7.5/31.7) in 2038.
The Net-Interest component of Total Spending
as a percentage of GDP is, of course,
derivative in that it cannot be controlled directly. It is ultimately
determined by GDP, the size of the debt, and the rate of interest that must
be paid on the debt. Since the rate of interest that must be paid
is ultimately determined by the willingness of individuals and
institutions to lend to the government, the only way the government can
affect Net-Interest as a percent of GDP is through it's ability to
control the size of the debt and through the effects of government budget
policies on GDP.
Examining the effects of government budget policies on
GDP is beyond the scope of this note.[2] The
discussion below is limited to examining how the structural relationships
between non-interest spending and the revenues collected by the federal
government can be expected to affect the federal debt to GDP ratio within
the CBO's alternative fiscal scenario.
The purpose of this discussion is to clarify the
nature of the
choices that must be made between increasing taxes and cutting Social Security,
Medicare, and the rest of the federal budget if we are to bring the
explosive rise in the projected debt to GDP ratio shown in Figure 1
under control.
Cutting Non-Interest Spending to
Control the Debt
The CBO refers to the amount by which taxes must
increase or expenditures must decrease (expressed as a percent of GDP) in
order to achieve the current debt ratio at the end of a specific period of
time as the "fiscal gap."[3]
Figure 2, uses a simple simulation model, based on the data in the Supplementary
Data that accompanied CBO's 2013 report, to show how a 15% decrease in
non-interest spending in the CBO's alternative fiscal scenario model, beginning in 2014,
can close the fiscal gap evident in Figure 1 by 2038.[4]
Figure 2: Reducing Projected Non-Interest Spending
by 15%
in the CBO's Alternative Fiscal Scenario.
(Percent of GDP) |
2013 |
2038 |
Difference |
% Change |
Debt/GDP |
73.0% |
73.0% |
0.0% |
0.0% |
Revenues |
17.0% |
18.1% |
1.1% |
6.5% |
Total Spending |
20.9% |
24.1% |
3.2% |
15.4% |
Surplus |
-3.9% |
-6.0% |
-2.1% |
54.5% |
Net Interest |
1.3% |
3.5% |
2.2% |
169.9% |
Non-Interest Spending |
19.6% |
20.6% |
1.0% |
5.2% |
Source: Simulation
of CBO model,
Office of
Management and Budget (Table
3.1).
This 15% decrease in non-interest spending leads to a
substantial decrease
in the
debt ratio in this simulation of the
CBO's model, from 73% of GDP in 2013 to
49% in 2025, as federal debt grows more slowly than GDP. Beginning
in 2025, this ratio then begins to increase, returning to 73% of GDP by 2038.
With regard to Total Spending, the end result
is an increase from 21% to 24% of GDP by 2038, a 3 percentage point
increase as
opposed to the 11 percentage point increase in Figure 1, while the increase in
Revenues remain unchanged at 1% of GDP.
The 8 percentage point drop in projected Total
Spending arises from Non-Interest Spending increasing by only 1
percentage point as a result of the 15% cut in Non-Interest Spending
rather than by the 4.6 percentage point increase shown in Figure 1. Net-Interest increases by only 2 percentage points rather than
by the 6 percentage points shown in Figure 1.
The question is, if we were to take this course in
attempting to close the fiscal gap—specifically, cutting spending without
increasing taxes—what federal programs would we have to cut in order to
achieve this 15% reduction in non-interest spending?
Breaking Down Non-Interest
Spending
Figure 3 breaks down Non-Interest Spending into the sum of our three major entitlement programs
(Social Security +
Medicare
+ Medicaid) and All Other
Non-Interest Spending from 1950 through the twenty-five year projection
period shown in Figure 1. This is where the actual cutting in
the budget must take place if we are to bring federal debt under control
through spending cuts alone.
Figure 3: Non-Interest Spending, Entitlements, and Everything
Else,
1950-2038.
(Percent of GDP) |
2013 |
2038 |
Difference |
%Change |
Non-Interest Spending |
19.6% |
24.2% |
4.6% |
23.5% |
Social Security+Medicare+Medicaid
|
9.6% |
14.6% |
5.0% |
52.1% |
All Other Non-Interest, Spending |
10.0% |
9.6% |
-0.4% |
-4.0% |
Source:
The 2013 Long-Term Budget
Outlook (Supplementary
Data),
Office of
Management and Budget (Table
3.1
Table 11.3).
This figure shows the primary reason for the projected
increase in non-interest spending in Figure 1, namely, the 5 percentage point projected increase in
our major entitlement programs,
Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. All Other Non-Interest
Spending is actually projected to decrease by 0.4% of GDP over the next
twenty-five years in the CBO's model.[5]
It should at least be apparent from Figure 3 that stabilizing
the federal budget through spending cuts alone would require substantial cuts
in our major entitlement programs,
Social Security,
Medicare,
and Medicaid.
All Other Non-Interest Spending has already been cut by 3.8% of GDP from 1980 through 2013 and is projected to decrease by an additional 0.4% of GDP by 2038. That
amounts to a 30% (0.304=4.2/13.8) cut in All Other Non-Interest Spending
relative to the size of our economy since 1980. In order to close the
fiscal gap by cutting All Other Non-Interest Spending alone would
require an additional 34% (0.344=3.3/9.6) cut in the government programs in
this category of the budget.
As I have argued elsewhere,
this just isn't going to happen. It will simply be impossible to make the
requisite cuts in defense, the Department of Justice, foreign
affairs, transportation, science and technology, conservation and pollution
control, education, welfare, public health, our regulatory and other public
service agencies in the absence of an increase in taxes without substantial
cuts in our major entitlement programs.
Eliminating Medicaid
That leaves our three major entitlement programs—Social
Security, Medicare, and Medicaid—and it is worth noting that the debt
ratio of 73% of GDP in 2038 cannot be achieved in the CBO's model by cutting
Medicaid alone. In the absence of an increase in Revenues
or a cut in some other portion of the budget, even if Medicaid were completely
eliminated the debt ratio would still increase to over 80% of GDP by 2038 in the
CBO's alternative fiscal scenario.
Increasing Taxes to Control the
Debt
Figure 4
provides a simulation to show how
a
17% increase in revenues in the CBO's
alternative fiscal scenario, beginning in 2014, can close the fiscal gap by
achieving a 73%
debt ratio in 2038.
Figure 4: Increasing Revenues by 17% in the CBO's
Alternative Fiscal Scenario.
(Percent of GDP) |
2013 |
2038 |
Difference |
% Change |
Debt/GDP |
73.0% |
73.0% |
0.0% |
0.0% |
Revenues |
17.0% |
21.2% |
4.2% |
24.9% |
Total Spending |
20.9% |
27.7% |
6.8% |
32.4% |
Surplus |
-3.9% |
-6.4% |
-2.5% |
65.2% |
Net Interest |
1.3% |
3.5% |
2.2% |
167.3% |
Non-Interest Spending |
19.6% |
24.2% |
4.6% |
23.5% |
Source: Simulation
of CBO model,
Office of
Management and Budget (Table
3.1).
In this simulation, the 17% increase in Revenues,
again, leads to a substantial decrease in the
debt ratio from 73% of GDP in 2013 to 48% in
2025 as the federal debt grows more slowly than GDP. Beginning in 2025
this ratio then begins to increase back to 73% of GDP by 2038. At the
same time, Non-Interest Spending increase by 4.6 percentage points as
in Figure 1.
In comparison with Figure 1 we find that
the net effect of this increase in revenue is to decrease the
projected level of Total Spending in 2038 from 32% of GDP to 28%
of GDP—a
4 percentage point increase in Total Spending as a result of the
17% revenue increase
in Figure 4 as apposed to the 11 percentage point increase in
Figure 1 without a revenue increase. At the same time,
Revenues increase from 17% of GDP to 21% of GDP—a 4 percentage
point increase in Revenues in Figure 5 as apposed to the 1
percentage point increase in Figure 1.
The question is, can we afford this kind of tax
increase in order to avoid dramatic cuts in Social Security, Medicare, and
Medicaid?
Taxes in the Real World
There is a pervasive feeling among the American people
that we are terribly overtaxed. In comparison with the other advanced countries of the world, this is not so. The table in
Figure 5 shows the
percent of GDP paid in total taxes by the thirty-four
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD) countries in 2010 (the
most recent year for which complete set of data is available) ranked from highest to
lowest.
Figure 5: Total Taxes in OECD Countries Ranked from Highest to lowest, 2010.
Tax Revenues as a Percent of GDP, 2010 |
Denmark |
47.4% |
Germany |
36.2% |
Canada |
30.6% |
Sweden |
45.4% |
Iceland |
35.2% |
Slovak Republic |
28.3% |
Belgium |
43.5% |
United Kingdom |
34.9% |
Switzerland |
28.1% |
Italy |
43.0% |
Estonia |
34.0% |
Japan |
27.6% |
France |
42.9% |
Czech Republic |
33.9% |
Ireland |
27.4% |
Norway |
42.6% |
OECD
Average |
33.8% |
Turkey |
26.2% |
Finland |
42.5% |
Spain |
32.5% |
Australia |
25.6% |
Austria |
42.2% |
Israel |
32.4% |
Korea |
25.1% |
Netherlands |
38.9% |
Poland |
31.7% |
United States |
23.8% |
Slovenia |
38.1% |
Greece |
31.6% |
Chile |
19.5% |
Hungary |
38.0% |
Portugal |
31.2% |
Mexico |
18.9% |
Luxembourg |
37.3% |
New Zealand |
31.1% |
|
|
Source:
OECD
Revenue Statistics - Comparative tables.
The United States ranks third from the bottom on this
list. We paid 30% less in taxes in 2010 than the average for the OECD countries,
40% less than the 17 countries that were above the average, 44% less
than the top 10 countries, and these are the most advanced and economically
productive countries in the world!
Federal revenues were equal to
15.1% of GDP in 2010. If we were to add the 1.9 percentage point
increase in federal revenue the CBO projects the federal government will be
taking in by 2013 to the 23.8% OECD estimate of our total government revenue
(federal, state, plus local)
in figure in Figure 5 it would bring our total to 25.7% of GDP. We would
then still be
fifth from the bottom among
the OECD countries (assuming that the numbers for the other countries are
unchanged) as listed in Figure 5, just below Turkey, and we would still be paying less in taxes than the average for these countries:
24% less that the average for all, 35% less than the average for
the 17 countries that are above the average in Figure 5, and 40% less
than the average for the top 10 countries.
And if we were to add the additional 2.9 percentage points required by the
17% federal tax increase needed to achieve
the 73% debt ratio in Figure 4 we would still be tenth from the bottom
with 28.6% of our GDP in total government revenue,
two percentage points below Canada, and we
would still be paying less than the average for the OECD countries: 10% less
that the average for all, 15% less than the average for the 17 countries that
are above the average in Figure 5, and 33% less than the average for
the top 10 countries.
It would appear from the table in Figure 5 that
the only obstacle to raising the taxes need to avoid dramatic cuts in Social
Security, Medicare, Medicaid, or the rest of the federal government is the
willingness to do so.
If two thirds of the most advanced countries of the
world can afford to pay the kinds of taxes needed to finance our government,
why can't we?
The Healthcare Nemesis
Figure 2 shows how a 15% decrease in
Non-Interest Spending can yield a 73% debt ratio in 2038 within the
CBO's alternative fiscal scenario and Figure 4 shows a similar result
for a 17% increase in
Revenues, but it is important to note that simply decreasing spending or
increasing taxes by these percentages will not solve the long-term federal
debt problem posed by the CBO's alternative fiscal scenario summarized in
Figure 1. After all, Debt/GDP is increasing from 2025
through 2038 in Figure 2 and Figure 4 even with the assumed decrease
in spending or cut in taxes. If the simulations in these figures were
extended through 2049 the result would be an increase in the debt ratio to 121% or 115% of GDP depending on whether we increase
revenues by 17% or decrease non-interest spending by 15% with the debt to
GDP ratio still increasing in 2049.
The reason for the dramatic increase in the debt ratio
after 2025 in the CBO's alternative fiscal scenario in spite of the 15%
spending cut or 17% tax increase can be seen in Figure 6 which shows the CBO's projections for Social Security, Medicare +
Medicaid, and All Other Non-Interest Expenditures through 2088.
Figure 6: Breakdown of Non-Interest Spending Projections,
1950-2088.
(Percent of GDP) |
2013 |
2088 |
Difference |
% Change |
Social Security |
4.9% |
6.7% |
1.8% |
36.7% |
Total Healthcare |
4.7% |
14.6% |
9.9% |
210.6% |
All Other Non-Interest, Spending |
10.0% |
9.6% |
-0.4% |
-4.0% |
Source:
The 2013 Long-Term Budget
Outlook (Supplementary
Data),
Office of
Management and Budget (Table
3.1
Table 11.3).
This figure clearly indicates the extent to which the
cost of healthcare dominates projected spending in the CBO's alternative
fiscal scenario. In this scenario, the CBO projects that even though
Social Security and All Other Non-Interest Spending are expected
to stabilize in the 2030s, the CBO's projections have Medicare + Medicaid
increasing as a percent of GDP more or less continuously through 2088.
Healthcare costs are projected to increase in this
scenario both
because as the population ages the baby boomers are in the process of
retiring and life expectancy is increasing. These demographic factors
are also expected to increase the cost of Social Security (26.5%
relative to GDP by 2038),
but not nearly as dramatically as the cost of healthcare is projected to
increase (78.7%
relative to GDP by 2038).
The importance of this discrepancy can be seen in
Figure 7 which combines an 17% revenue increase with restrictions on
the growth in Medicare and Medicaid spending that keep these programs in
line with the rate at which Social Security is projected to increase between
2013 and 2038.
Figure 7: Increasing Revenues by 17 and Keeping
Healthcare Increases
Inline with Projected Increases in Social Security, 1950-2049.
(Percent of GDP) |
2013 |
2049 |
Difference |
% Change |
Debt/GDP |
73.0% |
51.7% |
-21.3% |
-29.2% |
Revenues |
17.0% |
21.2% |
4.2% |
24.9% |
Total Spending |
20.9% |
24.3% |
3.4% |
16.4% |
Surplus |
-3.9% |
-3.1% |
0.8% |
-20.7% |
Social Security |
4.9% |
6.2% |
1.3% |
26.5% |
Medicare |
3.0% |
3.8% |
0.8% |
26.5% |
Medicaid |
1.7% |
2.2% |
0.5% |
26.5% |
Source: Simulation
of CBO model,
Office of
Management and Budget (Table
3.1).
The result is a substantial decrease in the debt ratio by 2038, but this ratio continues to increase after 2033
in the CBO's alternative fiscal scenario even when healthcare costs are brought under
control. What it would actually take to stabilize the debt in this
simulation of the CBO’s alternative fiscal model is combining the
restrictions on the growth in the cost of healthcare in Figure 7 with
a 21% increase in Revenues as is shown in Figure 8.
Figure 8: Increasing Revenues by 21% and Keeping
Healthcare Increases Inline with Social Security, 1950-2049.
(Percent of GDP) |
2013 |
2049 |
Difference |
% Change |
Debt/GDP |
73.0% |
38.9% |
-34.1% |
-46.7% |
Revenues |
17.0% |
22.0% |
5.0% |
29.3% |
Total Spending |
20.9% |
23.7% |
2.8% |
13.6% |
Surplus |
-3.9% |
-1.8% |
2.1% |
-54.9% |
Net Interest |
1.3% |
2.0% |
0.7% |
52.8% |
Source: Simulation
of CBO model,
Office of
Management and Budget (Table
3.1).
This has the effect of stabilizing the debt ratio at
around 40% of GDP, and this is what it would actually take to
stabilize the budget in the CBO's alternative
fiscal scenario—a substantial increase in taxes while keeping healthcare costs inline with the increases in Social Security
that are expected to occur as the baby boomers retire.
Conclusion
The CBO's alternative fiscal scenario projections, and
those of the simulation model examined above, cannot be taken as a literal
prediction or forecast of the future in that they are, at best, rough
approximations. In addition, they do not take into account the effects
of changes in government spending and tax increases on the overall level of
economic activity and the feedback effects these changes have on the budget.
Nor do they take into account the kinds of unforeseeable events that can and
do take place over any twenty-five or thirty-six year period—events such as
wars, natural disasters and financial and other kinds of economic
crises—that have dramatic effects on the federal budget.
At the same time, these models and projections provide
a broad framework within which to understand our fiscal problems. In
attempting to understand these problems within this framework it seems to me
that we are driven to two inescapable conclusions.
The first is that it is going to be impossible to
maintain Social Security and Medicare without dramatic cuts in the benefits
of these programs in the future unless we increase taxes. The only way
the debt ratio can be be stabilized if these programs are maintained without
an increase in taxes is if there are dramatic cuts in the rest of the
budget. As I have noted above, and have argued elsewhere, this just isn't going
to happen. It will simply be impossible to make the requisite cuts in defense,
the Department of Justice, foreign affairs, transportation,
science and technology, conservation and pollution control, education,
welfare, public health, our regulatory and other public service agencies in the absence of
an increase in taxes without substantial cuts in our major entitlement
programs. This means Social Security and Medicare since more than
80% of the money spent on our major entitlement programs is spent on
Social Security and Medicare, and less than
20% is spent on Medicaid.
The second inescapable conclusion, as Figure 6
through Figure 8 should make clear, is that it is going to be
virtually impossible to maintain the benefits of Medicare if we don't find a way to control
the rising cost of healthcare in the private sector of the economy, and, ultimately, this means we must find a way to implement some kind of
single-payer,
universal healthcare system if Medicare is to survive. This is so because
the primary reason federal healthcare costs have risen so
dramatically over the past seventy-five years is the
anachronistic
multiple-payer, third-party, fee-for-service payment system
we rely on in the private sector of our economy whereby healthcare providers set the price and tell patients what
services they need, and insurance companies pick up the
tab. This system virtually guarantees continually increasing costs since the decisions as
to what to prescribe and how much to charge are made primarily by healthcare
providers—doctors and hospitals—the very people and institutions that benefit the most from increasing healthcare costs.
Healthcare consumers
play a very limited role in this decision-making process.
This archaic,
multiple-payer, third-party,
fee-for-service payment scheme has caused the
American healthcare system to become most expensive and the least efficient among the advanced
countries of the world.
Every country that has better health statistics than we do has
abandoned the cost ineffective multiple-third-party-payer system for a
single-payer,
universal healthcare system that provides government subsidized healthcare for
all—paid for through taxes—where costs are controlled through government
negotiated prices. They pay higher taxes than we do, but their higher taxes
are more than offset by the savings in insurance premiums and lower healthcare
costs—not to mention the fact that they are
healthier than we are, and they live longer than we do.
(OECD
OECD Charts NYT
IOM
JAMA1
JAMA2)
Even though the
Affordable
Care Act promises to improve the health of our
population by increasing the availability of healthcare,
there is little reason to believe this Act will lead to substantial savings to
taxpayers in the absence of a
public
option. It is either a public option or some other kind of
single-payer
mechanism that makes it possible for healthcare costs to be controlled in
those countries that have better health statistics and lower healthcare costs than we do, and there is
little reason to believe we will be able to control our healthcare costs,
and, at the same time, maintain the health of our population
as we stabilize the federal budget unless we implement a similar system at home.
Finally, I would note that if we were to increase
taxes by the 21% needed to stabilize the budget in Figure 8, and if rising healthcare
costs were brought in line with the growth of Social Security through the
implementation of some kind of
single-payer
mechanism, it would add an additional 5.6 percentage points our total taxes in
Figure 5. This would increase the total government tax receipts in the
United States to 29.4% of GDP, but we would not only eliminate our fiscal
problems in the process, we would not be forced to cut the benefits of either Social
Security, Medicare, or Medicaid in the future.
This may seem to be an exorbitant price to pay for
these programs, but government programs are not free, and it is a fantasy to
think we can maintain Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid without
collecting the taxes needed to pay for these government programs. If
we want to maintain these programs we have to pay the price, and if we were
to pay this price while, at the same time, controlling the cost of
healthcare by implementing some form of universal,
single-payer
healthcare system
we would still be 10th from the bottom among the most
advanced countries in the world in terms of the percent of GDP collected in
taxes, just below Canada, and we would still be paying less than the average
for these countries: 13% less than the average for all, 26% less than the
average for the top 17, and 31% less than the average for the top 10.
Endnotes
[1]
Spending was projected to be higher under the alternative fiscal
scenario than under the baseline scenario in the CBO's 2013 report
because the CBO assumed
. . . that the automatic reductions in spending required by
the Budget Control Act for 2014 and later will not occur
(although the original caps on discretionary appropriations
in that law are assumed to remain in place); that
lawmakers will act to prevent Medicare’s payment rates
for physicians from declining; that . . . lawmakers
will not allow various restraints on the growth of Medicare
costs and health insurance subsidies to exert their full
effect; and . . . federal spending for programs
other than Social Security and the major health care programs
will rise to the average of other noninterest spending . . . as a percentage of GDP during the past two decades, rather than
fall significantly below that level, as it does in the extended baseline.
By the same token, revenues were projected to be lower under the alternative fiscal
scenario than under the baseline scenario because the CBO assumed
. . . that about 75 expiring tax provisions . . .
will be extended through 2023; and that after 2023, revenues will remain at
18.1 percent of GDP, matching their 2023 value and a little above the
average during the past 40 years of 17.4 percent, rather than rising over
time as a percentage of GDP, as they do in the extended baseline.
The 2013 Long-Term Budget Outlook.
[2]
I have examined the effects of government budget policies on GDP in depth in
Where Did All the Money Go? How Lower Taxes, Less
Government, and Deregulation Redistribute Income and Create Economic Instability.
[3] From the CBO's 2013 report:
The fiscal gap is a measure of the difference
between projected federal noninterest spending and revenues over a given
period. It represents the extent to which the government would need to
immediately and permanently raise tax revenues or cut spending—or do both,
to some degree—to make the government’s debt the same size (relative to
gross domestic product) at the end of the period that it is at the end of
2013.
The 2013 Long-Term Budget Outlook.
[4]
This simulation model is constructed by noting that federal debt at the end
of the current year (Di) will be approximately equal to a) the debt at the end of
the previous year (Di-1)
plus b) the interest paid out during the current year (Ii)
plus c) the non-interest expenditures paid out during the current year (NISi)
less d) the revenues collected during the year (Ri):
1) Di =
Di-1 + Ii + NISi - Ri.
This relationship is not exact in that it does not
take into account changes in the cash holdings of the federal government,
the accumulation or sale of assets, or the way in which other factors affect
cash flows that are not included in the budget, but it can be used to define
a model that roughly approximates the effects of changes in the OMB's
revenues and spending projections by specifying
2) Ii = riDi-1 + ri(Ri -
NISi) / 2
= ri(Di-1 + (Ri -
NISi) / 2),
where ri is an approximation to the average
rate of interest paid on the federal debt, and the other variables are as
defined in equation 1).
The significance of 2) is that this equation can be solved for
ri,
3) ri = Ii / (Di-1
+ (Ri
- NISi) / 2),
and, given the values for Di, Ri,
Ii and NISi in the
Supplementary Data that accompanies the
CBO's 2013 report, 3) can be used to estimate the values of
ri that are
implicit in the CBO's projection models. These estimated values can, in
turn, be substituted back into equation 1) to show how changes in
non-interest spending and revenues will affect the projected debt/GDP ratio
along with net-interest expenditures, total government expenditures, and
budget surpluses and deficits.
The nature of the estimates produced by this model is
examine in detail in Simulating the CBO's
Projection Models where I argue that it is reasonable to assume that
these estimates are within five to ten percent of the true values that would
be produced by the CBO's model. The Excel spreadsheets that were used to
derive the results from this model that are reported in this note can be
downloaded by
clicking on this link.
[5] It is worth noting that National Defense
is the largest single component of All Other Non-Interest Spending in Figure 3 which, according to the
Office of
Management and Budget, amounted to 41% of All Other Non-Interest
Spending in 2013 and is estimated to fall to 32% by 2018.
Since the CBO does not give a separate projection for National Defense I
have not attempted to deal with this component of the federal budget here,
but it is possible separate out defense expenditures in the simulation model
used in this note if one wishes to. See: Simulating the CBO's
Projection Models.