A Primer on Economic Crises
Part I: Origins of the Crash
George H. Blackford © 2008/9
Now that the election is over, a new
administration is in Washington, and there has been a host of congressional
hearings (Hearings)
investigating last fall’s financial crisis (NYT)
a consensus is beginning to emerge as to how this crisis came about. The
story begins with deregulation of the financial system.[1]
Four legislative acts
since 1980 have significantly reduced the power of government to control our
financial system:
-
Depository
Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act
(DIDMCA)
in 1980. This act eliminated
Regulation Q
that allowed the
Federal Reserve
to set maximum interest rates on bank deposits, and it also allowed
thrift institutions
to issue checking deposits and expanded the types of loans they could make.
-
Garn-St. Germain
Depository Institutions Act
(GGDIA)
in 1982. This act lowered the capital requirements of depository
institutions.
-
Financial Services
Modernization Act
(FSMA)
in 1999, also known as the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (GLBA).
This act repealed portions of the
Glass-Steagall Act
of 1933 by allowing commercial bank holding companies to become conglomerates
that are able to provide both
commercial
and
investment
banking services along with insurance and brokerage services.
-
Commodity Futures
Modernization Act
(CFMA)
in 2000. This act prevented the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC)
and state gambling regulators from regulating the
over-the-counter derivatives
markets,
including the market for credit default swaps (CDSs).
The evidence seems clear from the
testimony before congressional hearings in the fall of 2008 (Hearings)
by economists, lawyers, regulators, CEOs, and a host of others who are in some
way knowledgeable or personally involved in the financial crisis that passage
of these acts, and, specifically, the last two (FSMA
and
CFMA)
played a major role in the financial crisis of 2008. (Deregulation)
The tale told in these
Hearings
is that the passage of the Financial Services Modernization Act (FSMA)
and the Commodity Futures Modernization Act (CFMA)
combined with five other factors to bring about this crisis:
-
New economic models for evaluating the
risk of
securitized debt instruments were
created in the nineties. This led to an expansion in the markets for
Mortgage Backed Securities (MBSs),
Collateralized Debt Obligations (CDOs),
and other Asset Backed Securities along with the market for Credit Default
Swap (CDSs)
to insure these
assets.
-
There was a virtual explosion in the demand for
securitized assets and the concomitant Credit Default Swaps that insured
these assets that began after the passage of the Financial Services
Modernization Act (FSMA)
and the Commodity Futures Modernization Act (CFMA).
This increase in demand was fueled by the increasing
federal budget and foreign exchange
current account deficits that took place after 2000 and was financed by
the
Federal Reserve through a low interest rate policy that pumped
sufficient reserves into the financial system to maintain extraordinarily
low interest rates.
-
The increase in demand for securitized assets
led to an increase in the demand for the mortgages that were a major
component of these assets with a particular emphasis on
subprime and
alt-A mortgages since these were the most profitable for the mortgage
originators to sell. This led to an extraordinary expansion in the mortgage
origination business as mortgage originators expanded their operations to
meet this increased demand.
-
After the passage of the Financial Services
Modernization Act and the Commodity Futures Modernization Act the Federal
government lacked a comprehensive framework within which to regulate the
newly legitimized conglomerate banks. Nor did they have the legal authority
to regulate or the Credit Default Swaps (CDSs)
market.
-
An anti-regulation bias within the Federal
government led to a situation in which regulatory agencies were underfunded
and lacked the staff, resources, expertise, and motivation necessary to
effectively regulate the financial sector of the economy. The result was an
extraordinary lack of enforcement of existing regulations throughout the
financial system.
These five factors along with the
passage of the Financial Services Modernization Act
and the Commodity
Futures Modernization Act led to a financial regulatory system that was
totally inadequate. At the same time there was so much money to be made in
the
subprime,
alt-A,
and Mortgage Backed Securities (MBS)
markets that the temptation for recklessness, corruption, and fraud was
irresistible.
The problem started with mortgage
origination. Since there were not enough qualified
subprime
and
alt-A
borrowers to meet the demands for these kinds of mortgages, predatory mortgage
originators (such as
Countrywide
and
CitiFinancial)
talked a host of naive people into applying for these mortgages by
misrepresenting them to the mortgagor. The most serious misrepresentation was
to offer borrowers an
adjustable rate, negative amortization mortgage
with an unreasonably low initial (teaser)
rate without explaining the effect on their monthly payment when the initial
rate adjusted to the contract rate. Using this and other ploys (Spitzer),
borrowers qualified for modest subprime
mortgages at reasonable subprime rates were talked into applying for exorbitant
subprime
and alt-A mortgages at rates they could not
afford. Even borrowers qualified for modest prime rate mortgages at
reasonable prime rates were talked into applying for exorbitant
subprime and
alt-A
mortgages they could not afford. At the same time borrowers not qualified for
any kind of mortgage were approved for subprime
and alt-A
mortgages.
Next, in order to sell
these mortgages it was necessary for mortgage originators to obtain appraisals
of the underlying properties consistent with the values of the mortgages being
originated. To obtain these appraisals mortgage originators shopped around
for appraisers who would write consistent appraisals and shunned appraisers
who would not. This guaranteed a rising income for appraisers that cooperated
with the mortgage originators and a falling income for those that did not.
The result was a systematic upward bias in real-estate appraisals and, hence,
housing prices.
At this point real-estate
speculators got into the act. As housing prices rose, and speculators
discovered they could get
alt-A mortgages with no money down, a host of
disreputable speculators took out alt-A
mortgages knowing if the prices of their properties increased they would make
out like the bandits they were, and if the prices of their properties went
down they could walk away from these mortgages with little or no loss.
Firms that securitize mortgages were
the next link in the financial food chain that fed off these fraudulent
subprime
and
alt-A
mortgages. In order for investment banks and other firms that securitized
mortgages to sell their products (the Mortgage Backed Securities they created
from the subprime and
alt-A
mortgages) at the highest possible price they had to receive the highest
possible ratings from a bond rating agency. To accomplish this they followed
the lead of the mortgage originators to steer their business to bond rating
agencies that would give them the highest rating and away from those that
would give them a lower rating. In this way the companies that securitized
fraudulently obtained mortgages were able to get the three major bond rating
agencies (Moody’s,
Standard and Poor’s,
and
Fitch)
to give
triple-A
ratings to their Mortgage Backed Securities
that contained
these mortgages even though these bond rating agencies had no basis on which
to evaluate the quality of these securities.
As this process played itself out
from 2002 through 2007 literally millions of fraudulent obtained
subprime
and alt-A
mortgages provided the collateral for trillions of dollars of collateralized
securities that were spread throughout the financial system of the entire
world, and there was a failure of government regulation at every step in the
process to keep this from happening.
When state or local authorities
complained to the federal government about the
predatory lending
practices in their communities, not only did the Federal Reserve, which had
the absolute authority to stop these practices (Natter),
do nothing to clamp down on the mortgage market, the Bush Justice Department
actually went to court to keep state and local authorities from regulating
this market. (Spitzer)
As a result no restraints were placed on mortgage originators.
When the conglomerate banks created
after the passage of the Financial Services Modernization Act (FSMA)
came into existence in the absence of a comprehensive framework within which
to regulate them. This combined with the anti-regulation attitude of the
government made it possible for these banks to increase their
leverage
(i.e., the ratio of their debt to their equity) without effective oversight or
control. As a result, leverage grew in these institutions beyond all reason.
At the same time, no one paid any attention to the bond rating agencies as
they gave meaningless triple-A ratings to securities for which they had no
basis to justify these ratings. As a result, unsuspecting investors purchased
these securities without any idea how dangerously risky they were.
The most insidious failure of the
regulatory system, however, was the failure to regulate
the markets for Asset Backed
Securities (ABSs)
and Credit Default Swaps (CDSs)
while at the same time allowing the newly legalized conglomerate
entities to take the Mortgage Backed Securities (MBSs)
and other kinds of Asset Backed Securities (ABSs)
they were creating
off their balance sheets.
The importance of this last point
must be emphasized. To avoid the kind of financial crisis we are experiencing
today the amount of
leverage a
financial institution is allowed to have must be inversely related to the
riskiness of the assets held—the riskier the
asset the lower the leverage. The total leverage
(hence, the resulting risk implicit in this leverage) in the system as a whole
must be kept
at a level commensurate with the riskiness of the
assets
in the system.
When a financial institution
purchases financial
assets,
bundles them together, and sells Asset Backed Securities to other financial
institutions it creates a huge
liability on its balance sheet since it is responsible for the Asset Backed
Securities it sold that are backed by the financial
assets
it bundled. When it purchases Credit Default Swaps to insure the
assets
that backed the securities it sold it, in effect, ‘swapped’ the huge liability
for the promises of the
CDS
sellers of the Credit Default Swaps to assume (insure against loss) this huge liability for the financial
institution. This eliminates the financial institution’s liability, but
only to the extent the
CDS
sellers of the CDSs are, in fact, able to perform on their promises.
It may make sense, in theory, to
allow an individual institution to take its insured
assets
and corresponding
liabilities
off its balance sheet
(though this is highly dubious given the experience with
Enron
taking its obligations off its balance sheet) as it purchases Credit Default
Swaps to shed the risk associated with the securities it created, but only
if the market for Credit Default Swaps is regulated. If there are no
regulations on the institutions
that sell Credit Default Swaps there is no way to control the total amount of
leverage in the system as a whole since there is nothing to keep an
unregulated institution that sells
CDSs
from leveraging its equity at a 75 or 100 or higher to 1 ratio.
When this was allowed, financial
institutions that held
assets
which require something like a 12 to 1 leverage ratio for the system to be
safe shifted the risk associated with these assets
to financial institutions that leverage their equity at a 30 or 70 or whatever
they wanted to 1 ratio. This increases the leverage in the system as a
whole from the 12 to 1 ratio to whatever the leverage was in the
institutions that sold the assets
and thereby assumed the risk associated with the
assets.
Allowing financial institutions to
take their insured
assets
and corresponding
liabilities
off their balance sheets
when the institutions that insured these assets
where unregulated and the Credit Default Swaps that insured their
assets were traded in unregulated markets
made it impossible for regulators to even know what the total amount of
leverage (hence, the resulting risk implicit in this leverage) in the system
was, let alone keep this leverage at a level commensurate with the riskiness
of the assets
in the system. The result was an explosive increase in leverage in the system
as a whole and, hence, an explosive increase in the risk to the system as a
whole.
This situation was further
compounded by the fact that investors were able to buy Credit Default Swaps
for Asset Backed Securities even though the
investors had no connection to these securities. Combined with the failure to
control the leverage in the rest of the financial system, the result was an
explosion in the value of
CDSs
that grew to five or ten times the total value of the Asset Backed Securities
they insured as well as the explosion in the leverage created
in the financial system as a whole.
The failure to regulate the
CDS
market made this situation untenable because in the absence of regulation
there was no way to know the financial situations of the institutions that
sold Credit Default Swaps and how much leverage they contributed to the
system. In addition, there was no way to know the financial situation of
the entire
CDS
market—to know which of the sellers in this market were sound and which were
not. Hence, there was no way to know which Asset Backed Securities were
actually insured and which Asset Backed Securities were, in fact, not insured
by virtue of the fact that the sellers of the Credit Default Swaps
that insured them would be unable to meet their financial obligations.
The history of this period is yet to
be written, but to date virtually all of the economists, regulators, lawyers,
bankers, bond raters, and other individuals that either participated in, or in
some other way gained firsthand knowledge of this debacle that testified
before the congressional hearings on the financial crisis have agree that the
scenario laid out above is essentially what brought us to where we are today.
(Hearings)
The end result of these forces combined created a huge
speculative bubble
in the housing market where prices rose beyond all reason, and when this
bubble burst it brought down the system as a whole.
But why has the
bursting of this bubble cause so much turmoil in the economic system,
especially since only 2% or 3% of mortgages were in default at the beginning
of this crisis? To answer this question we have to begin with an
understanding of how the financial system works and the role it plays in the
economy.
Part II: The Nature of
Financial Institutions
Endnote
[1]
Since this piece was written in the fall of 2008 and updated in
2009 two comprehensive studies have come out that that fill in the details
of the broad outline presented in this paper of the causes of the
financial crisis that reached its climax in September of 2008. The first
is
The Financial Crisis Inquiry Report, Authorized Edition: Final Report
of the National Commission on the Causes of the Financial and Economic
Crisis in the United States
(2011) produced by the
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission. The second is the Majority and
Minority Staff Report of the Permanent Subcommittee On Investigations,
WALL STREET AND THE FINANCIAL CRISIS: Anatomy of a Financial Collapse
(2011).