Pollution, Natural Resources,
and Ideology*
George H. Blackford © 5/15/2013
Globalization, combined with technological improvements in
transportation and communication over the past thirty years have led to
incredible growth in productivity and output throughout the world.
Unfortunately, this growth is derived from the same
failed nineteenth century
ideological paradigm of free-market capitalism that led to the deregulation of
our financial system. This paradigm is terribly flawed in its failure to
understand the necessity to regulate financial markets or to understand
the
dependence of mass-production technologies on the existence of domestic mass
Markets. It is also terribly flawed in its failure to understand the necessity
to regulate pollution and to preserve our natural resources.
This nineteenth-century paradigm assumes
that the quantities of goods and services produced are determined in markets
through the interactions of buyers and sellers in such a way as to minimize
the costs of producing while at the same time maximizing the benefits to
society as a whole. The academic discipline of economics has provided a
logically consistent and mathematically elegant model of market behavior that
describes how this ideal system of human interaction is supposed to work as
well as the prerequisites for the existence for such a system to actually
work.
Unfortunately, the assumptions on which the
logical consistency of this model depends—the most
important being that no economic actor has the power to
directly influence
a market price, all market participants have
perfect
information as to the determination of all market prices, that there are
no external costs
or benefits associated with the production or consumption of any good, and
that
people behave rationally—are
impossible to achieve in the real world.[1]
The particular shortcoming of this
model I wish to discuss here is the problem of externalities.
At the core of the economic theory that explains how the benefits to
society as a whole are maximized in a market economy is the requirement that
market prices
reflect the costs to society as a whole that result from producing goods and
services and that market prices also reflect the benefits to society as a
whole that result from consuming the goods and services that are produced. This theory breaks down whenever
there are costs or benefits that are external to the process of
production or the act of consumption and, as a result, are not reflected in
the market price. (Musgrave)
To see how this breakdown occurs, consider the problem of disposing of the
toxic waste generated in the process of producing chemicals.
A chemical company can minimize the cost it must pay—its
private costs—to dispose of its toxic waste and, thereby, maximize its
profits, by simply dumping its waste into the nearest stream or ditch.
The polluted streams and aquifers that result threaten our supplies of potable
water and cost society dearly. When a chemical company is able to
externalize the costs of disposing of its toxic waste in this way, the private
costs of producing chemicals are substantially less than they would be if the
company had to pay these costs, and the true costs to society as a whole of
the chemicals produced are not reflected in their prices. This leads to
an over production of chemicals in the sense that if chemical companies had to
pay the true costs of producing chemicals, which would include the cost of
safely disposing of their toxic waste, the price
they would be willing to sell chemicals for would be
higher, less would be purchased, and less would be produced. (Smith
Kuttner
Musgrave)
What’s more, if chemical companies are not prevented by
law from dumping their toxic waste, they will have no choice but to dump it
because those companies that try to be socially responsible and dispose of their toxic
waste safely will have higher costs than those that do not try to be socially
responsible. As a result, socially responsible companies will be driven out
of business by socially irresponsible companies as irresponsible companies
drive market prices below the costs that must be paid by companies that try to
dispose of their toxic waste responsibly.
In other words, chemical companies must be forced by the
government to be socially responsible or they will be forced by the market to
be socially irresponsible. That’s how markets work, and the only alternative to
government intervention in the face of these kinds of external costs is to
allow the external costs to destroy the environment on which the human race
depends for its very existence.
This problem is, of course, not limited to
the chemical industry. The cheapest way to produce electricity is by
burning high sulfur coal and spewing the effluent into the atmosphere.
The acid rain and concomitant deforestation of the planet that result are
costs to society as a whole that are not reflected in the market price and are
not borne by the producers or consumers of electricity in the absence of
government regulation.
The
cheapest way to
run a nuclear power plant is to scrimp on safety, a practice which places
enormous geographical regions at risk of utter devastation, the costs of which
are not reflected in the market price of nuclear generated electricity and are
not borne by the producers or consumers of nuclear generated electricity in
the absence of government regulation.
The cheapest way to control pests in
agricultural is through the use of long lasting, carcinogenic chemicals such
as DDT which have devastating, long lasting consequences for human health and
the environment, the costs of which are not reflected in the market price and
are not born by the producers and consumers of agricultural products in the
absence of government regulation.
The cheapest way to make paint or gasoline
is by adding lead to the mix which spreads this toxic element throughout the
environment, the costs of which are not reflected in the market price and are
not born by the producers and consumers of paint or gasoline in the absence of
government regulation.
The list of dangers to the environment from unregulated
markets when there are external costs goes on and on, and the dangers are not
confined to external costs of production. There can be external costs of
consumption as well. The most obvious threat to the environment today is the
buildup of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere that is leading to global
warming. One of the largest sources of greenhouse gases is the carbon dioxide
produced by burning gasoline in the internal combustion engines that power our
automobiles. The threat to the planet is imminent, and there is no way
markets can deal with this threat because it arises from the external costs of
consuming gasoline, costs that are not reflected in the price of gasoline.
Since the price of gasoline does not come anywhere near
reflecting the costs to the world community from driving our cars, consumers
of gasoline do not have to pay these costs. Consumers of gasoline gain all of
the benefits of cheap transportation while they destroy the ecological balance
of the carbon cycle,
and there is no market mechanism that can keep this from happening in the
absence of government intervention. In fact, in the absence of government
intervention, it is inevitable that the market must destroy the carbon cycle
balance because it will always be cheaper and more convenient for most people
to drive cars than to utilize more fuel efficient forms of transportation so
long as those who drive cars have to pay only the private costs of producing
gasoline and do not have to pay the social costs of consuming gasoline.
There exists no mechanism within a market system of
economic organization to control the external costs of production and
consumption in the absence of government intervention, and it is inevitable
that a system of free markets that allows each individual and firm to force
the rest of the world to pay these costs will eventually destroy itself if the
government does not step in to keep this from happening.
Not only does the nineteenth century ideological paradigm
of unregulated free markets ignore the serious environmental problems that
result from external costs, this paradigm also ignores the voracious appetites
with which free markets devour natural resources. This aspect of
free-market
capitalism, along with the problem of pollution, was of little consequence in
the nineteenth century when the world’s population was but a fraction of what
it is today, when only a small fraction of world’s economy was industrialized,
and when the vast majority of the world’s population lived a communal
existence based on self sustaining, renewable technologies. The fact that a
relatively small industrialized sector of the world community consumed natural
resources at an accelerated rate and polluted the environment out of
proportion to its size was of little consequence in such a world. This is not
the case today.
Figure 1 plots the
United Nations estimates
of the world’s population from 1000AD through 2150.
It should be clear from this plot that today’s world is dramatically different
from what it was in the nineteenth century. The world’s population increased
by 68% in the 100 years from 1800 to 1900 as it went from 980 million to 1.65
billion. In the next 50 years it increased by another 53% to 2.5 billion. It
then increased dramatically as it went from 2.5 billion in 1950 to 6.06
billion by 2000, a 142% increase in just 50 years. Barring a worldwide
economic catastrophe, the world’s population is expected to increase by
another 50% in the next 40 years as it approaches 9 billion people by 2050. (UN
Sachs)
Source: United Nations,
The World at Six Billion.
Not only has the world’s population grown at an astounding
rate over the past fifty years, the world’s output of goods and services has
grown at an even more astounding rate, especially in recent years. As the
world’s population increased by 11% from 1980 through 2010, its output of
goods and services increased by almost 50%. At the same time the proportion
of the world’s output produced by the advanced countries fell from 80% in 1980
to 67% in 2010. (UN)
This 16% drop in the contribution of the advanced countries
to the total output of the world’s economy as total output increased by 50% is both gratifying and alarming.
Gratifying because it means a larger portion of the world’s output is being
produced by the less developed countries of the world with all of the potential that
holds for the improvement in economic well being for the impoverished in those
countries. At the same time it is alarming because that increase in output is
based on a flawed economic paradigm that is unsustainable.
The tremendous increase in economic productivity and output
that has made the remarkable increase in the world’s population possible over
the past three-hundred years have come from technological advances that have
allowed us to harness the energy stored in but three natural resources,
namely, coal, oil, and natural gas. In the eighteenth and nineteenth
centuries we mastered the technology of coal, and in the twentieth century we
mastered the technology of oil and natural gas. Today’s economic system
depends crucially on these three natural resources, especially oil, all of
which are nonrenewable and all of which pose a serious threat to the
environment.
As was noted above, this was of little consequence in the
nineteenth century when the world’s population was relatively small and a
relatively small sector was industrialized, but in the twenty first century
with the world’s population approaching nine billion people and the entire
world striving toward industrialization, the nonrenewable nature of our
resources and the inevitable consequences of accelerating pollution cannot be
ignored. The economic output of the world would have to increase by a factor of 3.5 over the next forty years to bring the rest of the world’s population up to
the standard of living enjoyed by the advanced countries today even if there
were no increase in the world’s population or in the standard of living in the
advanced countries. The increase would have to be by a factor of 4.6 if
the world’s population were to rise to the expected nine billion, and even
more if the standard of living in the advance countries were to increase as
well.[2]
The math is irrefutable, and there is no way unregulated free markets are
going to defeat this math.
With the incredible advances in transportation that have
evolved over the past sixty years, combined with the unimaginable network of
instant worldwide communication that came into being during the last twenty,
the drive for industrialization in today’s world cannot be stopped. The
concomitant effects on the environment and the limitations placed on
development by the finite nature of our natural resources—specifically, oil
but
potable water as well—must be acknowledged and dealt with if widespread
famine and starvation are to be avoided in the future. (Sachs)
In dealing with the problems of pollution and dwindling
natural resources, free-market ideologues are in a state of
denial. When it comes to global warming they argue 1) there is no such thing
as global warming, 2) even though there is global warming it’s not our
fault, and 3) if the government will just get out of the way free markets will
solve the problem. (PRC)
In dealing with the problem of preserving our natural resources they insist
that the actions of free individuals in unregulated free markets that are free
of government intervention will solve these problems without our having to
worry about them.
It is worth keeping in mind, however, that
these are the same people who
deregulated our financial
system,
facilitated the concentration of monopoly power into the hands of larger and
larger, too-big-to-fail institutions, guided our trade policies into
continuing trade deficits and the outsourcing of our manufacturing sector,
failed to enforce laws against fraud and unfair labor practices, and imposed a
tax structure on the populace that is incapable of maintaining the
public
infrastructure and
social capital from
which those at the top of the income distribution have benefited so greatly—the
same people whose policies
undermined our mass markets and drove the world’s financial system to the
brink of destruction. And these
same free-market ideologues are now blaming “entitlement programs” for the
economic catastrophe their policies have created as they block the tax
increases needed to deal with the resulting deficit/debt problem and insist on
cutting Social Security, Medicare, and other social-insurance programs in
order to balance the federal budget.
Given this record, it is difficult to
understand why anyone would take these people seriously, but, unfortunately,
much of the electorate does take them seriously, as does the leadership of
both the Republican and Democratic parties.
Over the past thirty years free-market
ideologues have been able to block virtually every attempt to
deal with the problems posed by rapidly rising external costs brought about by
rapidly increasing population and economic growth in a world economy fueled by
nonrenewable natural resources. Their influence in the United States has led to
Carter’s energy
program being dismantled in the 1980s,
CAFÉ standards
that barely changed after 1984 until gasoline prices peaked in the mid 2000s, funding for the cleanup of
superfund toxic waste sites being
allowed to expire in 1995, the United States walking away from the
Kyoto Protocol
on global warming in 2001, and water pollution restrictions being reduced in
2003. (Hartmann
NHTSA GAO
Time
CSM)
Their continued success in this regard does not bode well
for the future. Aside from the problem of global warming, the
transportation and agricultural systems we have developed as a result of
modern technology depend crucially on oil. These systems have led to
incredible increase in productivity over the past fifty years, but in the face
of increasing world population and economic growth this
technology is unsustainable.
As world oil reserves dwindle and the demand for oil
increases, the price of oil must increase, and, in turn, the productivity of
our transportation and agricultural systems must decline. Until we are
able to find a renewable source of energy to replace oil, prospects for the
future are dim. In the meantime, it is going to become more and more
difficult to feed the world’s population, and a rise in conflict, political instability, and turmoil throughout the world is inevitable. (EB)
If we value the kind of world we leave to our children and
grandchildren we cannot sit back and hope for the best as unregulated markets
squander our natural resources and pollute our planet. The problems
posed by population growth, the drive to industrialize, and the finite nature
of our natural resources cannot be solved by markets alone. They can
only be solved through the international cooperation of governments. (Sachs)
Endnotes
*
This essay was at one time,
Chapter 19 in
Where Did All the Money Go?
[1]
It is, perhaps, worth noting
that this fact is well known and well understood within the discipline of
economics and is accepted by virtually all who know anything at all about
the discipline or about the world in which we actually live. It’s not open
to debate except, of course, among those who are either completely out of
touch with reality or who make their living by denying this fact.
[2] The
populations in these calculations are derived from the following table taken from the
International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database:
Country
Group Name |
Subject
Descriptor |
Units |
Scale |
2010 |
Adv. economies |
GDP(PPP) |
Cur.Int.dollar |
Billions |
38,693.78 |
Adv. economies |
GDP(PPP)/capita
|
Cur.Int.dollar |
Units |
38,024.65 |
Adv. economies |
Population |
|
Billions |
1.01 |
Emrg. & dev. economies |
GDP(PPP) |
Cur.Int.dollar |
Billions |
34,505.83 |
Emrg. & dev. economies |
GDP(PPP)/capita
|
Cur.Int.dollar |
Units |
5,953.64 |
Emrg. & dev. economies |
Population |
|
Billions |
5.80 |
where population is estimated by
dividing GDP(PPP) by GDP(PPP)/capita.