These statements are supposed
to be reassuring, but they are not. After all,
there
have already been three or
four major accidents,
depending on how
we count the
Enrico Fermi meltdown, in the 59 year history of the
industry.
What
difference does it make if modern designs meet a calculated 1 in 100,000 year standard
and the best plants meet a calculated 1 in 1 million year standard when the current
governmental mandated standard is 1 in 10,000 years, and the actual history
of the industry worldwide is 1 in 4,833 reactor-years (14,500 / 3) or 1 in
every 3,625 reactor-years (14,500 / 4) if we include the
Enrico Fermi meltdown?
And even if the US government were able to achieve its calculated 1 in
10,000 reactor-years accident rate, there are
104 nuclear power plants in the US today that
produce
20% of our electricity.
If we were to increase to the 520 plants it would take to obtain all of our
electricity from nuclear power (104 / 0.2) this accident rate would imply,
on average, a
Three Mile Island type accident—or
worse—once
every twenty years (10,000 / 520).
It is fairly obvious that an acceptably safe nuclear power industry cannot
be achieved with a calculated 1 in 10,000 year mandate, but even if the
government were to mandate the calculated 1 in 1 million year rate that the
best plants are supposed to be operating at today, there is no reason to
believe this would solve the problem
because there is
no reason to believe that the calculated numbers scientists and nuclear
engineers come up with in
theory
with regard to the safety of nuclear power will
actually be achievable in
practice.
How effective
can we reasonably expect the government to be in enforcing the requirements
of a 1 in 1,000,000 standard in a situation in which millions of
dollars are at stake and companies can increase their profits
by ignoring these requirements and
avoiding regulation as much as possible? This problem is particularly
daunting in an industry where the calculated probabilities of an accident
are exceedingly low and
the consequences of ignoring a regulation are seemingly unlikely and distant
while the benefits to be gained appear to be large and immediate.
The situation with nuclear power today is very
much the same as it was with the financial system leading up to the crisis
in 2008. The scientists and financial engineers were able to convince the
government and its regulators that, in
theory,
sophisticated financial innovations and allowing financial institutions to
regulate themselves would make the financial system more efficient and
productive. In
practice,
it didn’t work out that way as the government and its regulators failed to
implement and enforce the regulations that would have been necessary to keep
the financial system from melting down in 2008. (See
Where Did All the Money Go?)
If the government can’t
even regulate something as seemingly benign as a bank safely in this kind of
a situation, why would we believe the government can regulate something as
dangerous as a nuclear power plant safely? And it’s not just the construction and operation of
nuclear power plants that have to be regulated by the government. The
production of nuclear fuel,
disposal of nuclear waste, and the
decommissioning of nuclear power plants all pose
serious health threats to the public that require strict government regulation to
keep the public safe.
The government’s record
has not been particularly stellar in this regard as the experiences at
West Valley,
Hanford,
Three Mile Island, and
innumerable nuclear waste sites throughout the
country will attest. Nor has it been particularly stellar in dealing with
the problems of
toxic
waste in general as the experiences at
Love Canal and
tens of thousands of hazardous waste sites
throughout the country today will attest. It would take an
unimaginable faith in government regulation and government regulators in the
face of overwhelming evidence to the contrary to believe that the
government, through its regulatory power, can or will make the production of
nuclear power safe.
Not only is there no reason to
believe that government regulation can make the production of nuclear power
safe, there is also no reason to believe that, in the absence of government
subsidies to defray the extraordinary costs in the nuclear power industry,
nuclear power can be produced at a lower costs than various sources of
renewable energy that can be developed. In fact, there is no reason to
believe that very many, if any, of our current nuclear power plants would
have been built without being subsidized by the federal government through
the
Price-Anderson Act of 1957 which provides limited liability
protection against catastrophic loss by nuclear power companies in the event
of a serious accident.
The importance of the
Price-Anderson Act to the development of nuclear power is
spelled out in the following statement from the
World Nuclear Association's website:
By limiting the amount that
operators would have to pay, the risks of an accident are effectively
socialized. Beyond a certain level of damage, responsibility is passed
from the individual operator either on to the State or a mutual collective
of nuclear operators, or indeed both. In essence this limitation
recognizes the benefits of nuclear power and the tacit acceptance of the
risks a State takes by permitting power plant construction and operation,
as with other major infrastructure.
In
other words, the
Price-Anderson Act means that, by federal law, nuclear power companies
do not have to pay the total cost of insuring against all of the damages that
may result from a catastrophe these companies cause. They only have to pay the cost
of insuring against damages up to a cap. The cost of insuring against
catastrophic
damages that occur above the cap are shifted to the taxpayer. It
is fairly safe to say that without this government subsidy that allows
nuclear power companies to shift these costs to taxpayers there would be
far fewer nuclear power plants in the US today.
Finally, I would note that even though there are huge tradeoffs between safety
and cost in nuclear power industry and other problems that make it virtually
impossible for the government to regulate this industry safely, there are at
least three things that can
be done to make the production of nuclear power safer.
The first is to junk the
current NRC theoretical standard limiting a serious accident to 1 in 10,000
years and mandate a 1 in a million year standard instead. This will not make nuclear power safe
in practice, but it will at least set the theoretical standard above one
where switching over to nuclear power implies a
Three Mile Island type accident
or worse every twenty years.
The second is to
repeal that portion of the
Price-Anderson Act that subsidizes nuclear power companies.
Eliminating the insurance caps and forcing nuclear power companies to pay
the full cost of insuring against all potential damages that may result from
their negligence will have the effect of making the true cost of nuclear
power better reflected in the market price of electricity. This will lower the expected profits that can be made by building nuclear power
plants and will lead to far fewer nuclear power plants being built.
The third is to provide stiff criminal penalties for the
willful violation of any NRC safety regulation. This will simplify the
decision-making process
in the nuclear power industry from one in which those in charge are forced to
chose between:
following the rules and costing the company a lot of
money and, perhaps,
damaging their chances for promotion within its management structure
or ignoring the rules and risking a serious, though highly unlikely,
accident
to
one in which their choice is between:
following the rules or going to jail.
This, of course, will not solve the
problem, but it will, at least, make the enforcement of government
regulations somewhat more effective by adding a further
incentive for those in charge
of producing nuclear power to follow the rules.