Prologue and
Chapter 1
From
Where Did All The Money Go?
How Lower Taxes, Less Government, and Deregulation Redistribute Income and
Create Economic Instability
Amazon.com
[T]he ideas of economists and political
philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more
powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed, the world is ruled by little
else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any
intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist.
Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy
from some academic scribbler of a few years back. I am sure that the power
of vested interests is . . . exaggerated compared with the gradual
encroachment of ideas. Not, indeed, immediately, but after a certain
interval; for in the field of economic and political philosophy there are
not many who are influenced by new theories after they are twenty-five or
thirty years of age, so that the ideas which civil servants and politicians
and even agitators apply to current events are not likely to be the newest.
But, soon or late, it is ideas . . . which are dangerous for good or evil.
John Maynard Keynes
A new scientific truth does not triumph by
convincing its opponents and making them see the light, but rather because
its opponents eventually die, and a new generation grows up that is familiar
with it.
Max Planck,
I
am a state-school economist. By that I mean I had the privilege of teaching
undergraduate economics students at state colleges and universities for some
twenty years prior to 1987. I believe this gives me a perspective on the
discipline of economics that is somewhat different from those who have not
been equally blessed. It also helps that I left academia in 1987 and no
longer had to deal with the revolution that had been taking place in the
discipline for some time—a revolution that seems to have come to fruition in
2008.
I
spent the twenty years leading up to 2008 reading mostly mathematics and
statistics books and paid little attention to the real world other than to
watch the news. The financial crisis that reached its climax in that year
took me entirely by surprise. I knew there was a problem in the housing
market and that economic nonsense had been at the center of the political
debate in our country for over thirty years, but I assumed, naively it
turned out, that cooler heads would prevail, and sound economic policies
would always be enforced. I had no idea our financial institutions would be
allowed to overextend themselves to such an extent they could bring down the
economy of the entire world. After the crash I decided to set aside other
pursuits and try to find out what had been going on in the world of
economics since I left academia.
When I began this quest I was stunned to find the extent to which
free-market ideological beliefs had taken over the discipline of economics.
I have a decidedly pragmatic, nonideological view of the world derived from
an inductive analysis of history and real-world observations aided by
deductive reasoning. I emphatically reject any ideological view that begins
with first principles and attempts to deduce from those principles the way
the world works aided by inductive analysis when history and real-world
observations are consistent with those principles and oblivious when they
are not.
I
consider myself neither a
freshwater (Chicago
School) nor a
saltwater (Keynesian)
economist, to use the terms coined by
Robert Hall and
recently revived to describe the most
important division within the discipline of economics today, but rather one
who attempts to find the truth and reject the nonsense wherever it may be.
If anything, I identify with the traditions of
Institutional Economics as exemplified by the
writings of
Thorstein Veblen,
Karl Polanyi, and
John Kenneth Galbraith though the influences
of
Adam Smith,
John Stuart Mill,
Alfred Marshall,
John Maynard Keynes,
Paul Samuelson, and
Milton Friedman are hard to deny, especially
since I was trained within the traditions of
Neoclassical Economics.
My rejection of ideology means, of course, that I totally reject the
ideological dogma that has defined freshwater economists
since the 1930s. I have always seen their
elevation of “economic
liberalism and free markets above all else”
and their relentless struggle against “government
intervention” in the economic system as being
incomprehensibly naïve if not outright paranoid.
As for saltwater economists, at least they are not hobbled by the
ideological blindness created by the doctrinaire approach of freshwater
economists, but their adherence to neoclassical methodology leads to a kind
of
streetlight effect as personified by the man
who lost his keys in the park but looks for them under the streetlight
because “this
is where the light is.” Neoclassical
methodology hinders the ability of saltwater economists to see problems and
seek solutions that exist
beyond the light shed by their neoclassical models.
It seems to me this leads to a problem in their ability to understand how we
got to where we are today and in formulating effective policies to deal with
the root cause of the economic problems we face. This can be seen in the way
their neoclassical models lead freshwater economists to recommend expansive
monetary policy combined with increasing government expenditures and
decreasing taxes to deal with the economic problems created by the
housing bubble bursting. These policies,
undoubtedly, would have solved our employment problem had they been
forcefully applied, but they offer only a short-run solution to this
problem, and they do not come to grips with the fundamental long-run problem
we face today.
An extraordinary level of monetary expansion was absolutely essential to
maintain the stability of the financial system during the crisis in 2008,
but there is little reason to believe the
quantitative easing that followed has made
much of a positive contribution. Even if this policy is successful in
reducing real rates of interest and thereby increasing investment and
employment, the redistribution effects of the inflation this policy relies
upon will do harm, and, in the end, could do more harm than good. This is
fairly obvious even within the context of Saltwater Economics. (Stiglitz
Summers)
As for increasing government expenditures and decreasing taxes, this is a
formula for increasing government deficits and debt. While this may provide
a short-run solution to our employment problem it also means increasing the
transfer burden on taxpayers as increasing interest payments are transferred
from taxpayers to government bondholders. Since government bondholders tend
to be among the wealthiest members of our society, increasing government
deficits is likely to have the added effect of increasing the
concentration of income at the top of the income distribution. This is a
problem that
is not clearly understood by saltwater
economists.
The fundamental difficulty faced by saltwater economists in attempting to
understand the problems caused by increase in the concentration of income is
that the distribution of income does not appear as a variable in the
neoclassical models from which saltwater analysis and, hence, saltwater
policy recommendations are derived. As a result, the effects of an
increase in the concentration of income on the economic system cannot be
examined within these models. (Stiglitz)
In order to find answers to questions about how an increase in the
concentration of income affects the economic system one must move out from
under the light shed by neoclassical models and into the non-neoclassical
park where the light is not so good. That’s where I have been for the past
five years.
As I recount my journey through the non-neoclassical park in the pages below
I come to the inescapable collusion that it was the ideological faith in the
self-adjusting powers of free markets on the part of policy makers over the
past forty years that has brought us to where we are today. This faith led
policy makers to 1) abandon the managed exchange system embodied in the
Bretton Woods Agreement, 2) institute the tax
cuts that have occurred since 1980, and 3) deregulate our financial system.
These policy changes made it possible for our financial institutions to
increase debt beyond any sense of reason. These policy changes also led to a
rise in our current account deficits (increasing debt to foreigners) and to
the financing of speculative bubbles which, when combined with the tax cuts
that have occurred since 1980, led to the increase in the concentration of
income at the top of the income distribution that we see today.
The resulting increase in the concentration of income has led us to what I
consider to be the fundamental problem we face today. Namely, that 1) given
the increased concentration of income, 2) the degree of mass-production
technology that exists within our economic system, and 3) the size of our
current account deficits it is impossible to sustain the mass markets needed
to fully employ our economic resources in the absence of a continual
increase in debt relative to income.
This is a problem because continually increasing non-federal debt relative
to income is unsustainable in the long run since it increases the transfer
burden on debtors as income is transferred from debtors to creditors through
the payment of interest. This means that eventually the system must
breakdown as interest payments increase and non-federal debtors eventually
find it impossible to meet their financial obligations. This leads to
financial crises in which the financial system must be bailed out by the
federal government to keep it from collapsing and bringing the rest of the
economic system down with it.
Continually increasing federal debt relative to income is a problem because
as interest payments on the federal debt grow they must eventually overwhelm
the federal budget. This will make it more and more difficult to fund
essential government programs such as Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid,
and national defense. And most important, as was noted above, an increase
in government debt is likely to contribute toward a further increase
the concentration of income. This will make the long-run problem we face
worse because a further increase in the concentration of income will
increase the rate at which debt must increase relative to income in order to
fully employ our resources. Even though the federal government has the legal
right to print the money needed to pay the interest on its debt, this does
not solve the problem since it is fairly certain that doing so on a
continual basis will eventually destabilize the economic
system.
As a result, I reject the saltwater policy of increasing government
expenditures and decreasing taxes that offers a
short-run solution to the problems we face in favor of a policy of
increasing government expenditures and increasing taxes in a way that
1) reduces the concentration of income and our current account deficits, 2)
deleverages the non-federal sector of our economy, and 3) stabilizes the
federal debt relative to GDP.
This is the only long-run solution I have been able to find in the
non-neoclassical park I have been wandering in for the past five years. It
seems to me that if we do not increase both government expenditures and
taxes in a way that stabilizes the federal budget and reduces the
concentration of income and our current account deficits, our economic
situation can only get worse. In the absence of an increasing debt relative
to income our ability to produce will be diminished as our employment
problem is solved through the transfer of resources out of those industries
that produce for domestic mass markets (our most productive industries) and
into those that serve the wealthy few which
is, of course, exactly what has been happening in our economy over the past
thirty-five years. In addition, our diminished ability to produce through
the utilization of mass-production technologies portends stagnation or a
fall in the standard of living for the vast majority of our population which
is, of course, also exactly what has been happening for the past thirty-five
years.
This is the story I tell in the pages below, and, given the nature of the
debate within the discipline of economics today, I see little reason to
believe this story will change anyone’s mind. There is certainly no hope at
all that it will change the minds of freshwater economists as this story
flies in the face of
their most firmly held ideological convictions.
There is, of course, some hope it will motivate saltwater economists to
include the distribution of income as a variable in their models in a way
that allows them to investigate the effects of the concentration of income
on the viability of mass-production technology in the absence of increasing
debt. The only real hope, however, is with the young who have not yet formed
the opinions that will—for better or for worse—serve them for the rest of
their lives. It is to the young that I dedicate this eBook for it is with
the young that our hope for the future lies.
Chapter 1: Income, Fraud, Instability, and Efficiency
examines the policy changes that have occurred over the past forty years and
documents the consequences in terms of the increase in the concentration of
income, fraud, economic instability, and economic inefficiency that followed
in the wake of these changes.
Chapter 2: International Finance and Trade
examines the consequences of these policy changes within the context of
international trade and finance and documents the consequences of these
changes in terms of the resulting increase in international economic
instability and the effects of the resulting balance of payment deficits on
domestic producers.
Chapter 3: Mass Production, Income, Exports, and Debt
examines the historical relationship between the rise of mass-production
technologies in the United States over the past one hundred years and 1) the
current account surplus, 2) the concentration of income, 3) the creation of
mass markets, 4) changes in debt, and 5) economic instability. It also
explains the fundamental thesis of this work. Namely, the extent to which a
society is able to take advantage of mass-production technology is limited
by the extent of its mass markets which, in turn, are limited by 1) the
distribution of income within that society, 2) the extent of its current
account surplus, and 3) the extent to which it is possible to increase debt
relative to income.
The
next seven chapters are devoted to explaining how our financial system works
and why an unregulated financial system leads to the increases in debt and
the concentration of income that result in economic instability.
Chapter 4: Going Into Debt explains the nature of financial
intermediation and examines the relationship between the deregulation of our
financial system and the resulting increase in debt that has occurred since
1980. The way in which
ideological beliefs came to dominate policy making in the United Sates
over the past forty years is discussed along with the way in which the
deregulation of our financial system led to the
housing bubble in the 2000s, its bursting in 2006, and the financial
crisis that began in 2007 just as the lack of financial regulation led to
the housing and stock-market bubbles of the 1920s, the Crash of 1929, and
the financial crisis that began in 1930.
Chapter 5: Nineteenth Century Financial Crises examines the problems of
nineteenth century banking, and explains how a
banking system works. This chapter presents the kind of explanation of
monetary expansion that can be found in most any economic principles or
money and banking textbook, but with a difference. Instead of focusing on
how banks create money, the focus is on how banks created debt and on how
this debt creation mechanism leads to economic instability in an unregulated
financial system.
Chapter 6: The Federal Reserve and Financial Regulation
explains 1) the way in which the Federal Reserve controls the amount of
currency available to the economy (i.e., the monetary base), 2) how this
system evolved in the United States during the
Great Depression, and 3) why the experiences
of the 1920s and 1930s led to a rejection of the
failed nineteenth century ideology of
Free-Market Capitalism in favor of a pragmatic
regime of regulated-market capitalism.
Chapter 7: Rise of the Shadow Banking System (and
the following chapter) examine how our financial system changed with the
revival of the
failed nineteenth century ideology of
Free-Market Capitalism that began among policy makers in the 1970s.
The nature of various kinds of financial
instruments is explained in this chapter along with the way in which
collateralization led to the rise of the shadow banking system.
Chapter 8: Securitization, Derivatives, and Leverage
explains the way in which income streams are securitized, the nature of
financial derivatives, and the way in which financial derivatives increase
leverage and, hence, in the absence of an exchange or clearinghouse,
increase instability in the financial system.
Chapter 9: LTCM and the Panic of 1998
chronicles the events that occurred during the
Panic of 1998 when a single hedge fund,
Long-term Capital Management, posed a threat
to the financial stability of the entire world. It is shown that all of the
dangers implicit in the way in which our financial system had been
deregulated were apparent to those who investigated this incident at the
time but that ideological blindness inspired by an almost religious faith in
free markets on the part of policy makers and elected officials made it
impossible to heed the
General Accounting Office’s warnings and
regulate shadow banks and the over-the-counter markets for derivatives.
Chapter 10: The Crash of 2008 chronicles the
financial crisis that began in 2007 and culminated in the near meltdown of
the world’s financial system in 2008. It argues that, given the way in which
our financial system had changed in the wake of the financial deregulation
that had occurred in the proceeding forty years, this crisis unfolded in a
very predictable way. It is also argues that it was the size of the
government and its active intervention in the economic system that kept the
system from collapsing. It further argues that if the government had not
been able to intervene in the way it did in the wake of the Crash of 2008 we
would have suffered the same kind of fate we suffered in the 1930s.
Chapter 11: Lessons from the Great Depression
examines the government’s response to the economic crisis during the Great
Depression and shows how the
conservative monetary and
fiscal policies advocated by
free-market ideologues today are the same policies
that drove the economy into the depths of the Great Depression in the 1930s
just as
they have had a similar effect on Europe since 2010.
It also argues that the kind of stagnation we experienced in the 1930s, and
are in the midst of today, requires decisive government action and that tax
increases played an important role in stabilizing the growth of federal debt
during the depression and following World War II.
Chapter 12: Coming to Grips with Reality
argues that today we face the same kind of situation we faced in the 1930s
when, given the degree of mass-production technology available in the
economy, the existing distribution of income and current account surpluses
could not provide the mass markets needed to achieve full employment in the
absence of an increase in debt relative to income. The only way we can
create the mass markets needed to achieve full employment—and sustain the
degree of mass-production technology that exists in our economy—in this
situation is by 1) increasing our current account surplus (i.e., reducing
our current account deficit), 2) increasing debt relative to income, or 3)
by reducing the concentration of income.
Given the size of our economy, we cannot solve our employment problem
entirely by increasing our current account surplus, (Stiglitz)
and since we have apparently reached a point at which further increases in
non-federal debt is no longer possible this leaves only 1) continually
increasing federal debt relative to GDP or 2) reducing the concentration of
income. Since continually increasing federal debt relative to GDP is, at
best, only a short-run solution and is likely to increase the concentration
of income further, this leaves reducing the concentration of income as the
only long-run solution that allows us to take full advantage of the
mass-production technology that is available to us.
If we do not reject the kind
of
ideological nonsense that has guided economic
policy for the past forty years and face this problem head on with a
substantial increase in government expenditures and taxes that are
specifically designed to 1) reduce the concentration of income, 2) achieve a
reasonable balance in our current account, 3) deleverage the non-federal
sector of the economy, and 4) rebuild the physical infrastructure and social
capital that we have allowed to depreciate over the past forty years our
economic situation will continue to deteriorate, and the standard of living
of the vast majority of our population will continue to stagnate or fall as
our ability to take advantage of mass-production technologies is diminished.
Chapter 1: Income, Fraud,
Instability, and Efficiency
There’s class warfare, all right, but it’s my
class, the rich class, that’s making war, and we’re winning.
Warren E. Buffett
The changes in economic policy that took place during the forty years
leading up to the financial crisis that began in 2007 are astounding. This
is particularly so when it comes to the tax code. The maximum marginal
income tax was reduced from
70% to 35%, the maximum capital gains tax from
28% to 15.7%, the maximum corporate profits
tax from
50% to 34%, the maximum tax on dividends from
70% to 15%, and the maximum marginal estate
tax from
70% to
35%. At the same time,
payroll taxes were increased as were taxes on
cigarettes,
gasoline, and other
sales and excise taxes as
government fees and fines and the
tuition at public colleges and universities
were increased as well. All of these changes have made our system of
government finance more
regressive—that is, they increased the
proportion of income taken by the government from low and middle-income
families relative to the proportion taken from upper-income families. (PCCW)
Changes in the area of market regulation have been particularly dramatic as
well. Much of our regulatory system had been dismantled, either through
legislative changes, deliberate
under funding of the regulatory agencies, or
through the appointment of individuals to head these agencies
who did not believe in regulating markets and
were willing to minimize the enforcement of existing regulations. (Frank
Kuttner
Amy
NYT
Bair)
A
third area of economic policy in which there have been profound changes is
in the area of international finance and trade. Of particular importance was
the abandonment in 1973 of the managed international exchange system set up
by the
Bretton Woods Agreement in 1944 and replacing
it with what became known as the
Washington Consensus which championed
unrestricted international finance and trade. This eventually led to
innumerable
bilateral trade agreements negotiated with China
after
Nixon's historic visit in 1972, the
North American Free Trade Agreement in 1994,
and our joining the
World Trade Organization in 1995. (Wilson
Stiglitz
Galbraith
Reinhart
Philips
Morris
Eichengreen
Rodrik)
All of these changes were championed in the name of economic efficiency and
have, in fact, made it possible for countless individuals to amass huge
amounts of wealth over the past forty years. What’s wrong with that? Haven’t
we all benefited from the generation of all that wealth? Well, not exactly.
It is instructive to look at how the distribution of income has changed
since the onset of the changes in economic policy outlined above.
Bottom 90%
Figure 1.1
shows the average real income (measured in
2012 prices, including and excluding capital gains) of all families in the
bottom 90% of the income distribution in the United States from 1917 through
2012. In 2012 this group consisted of 145 million families that received an
income (including capital gains) of $113,820 or less. The average income for
this group was $30,997 in 2012.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
It is clear from Figure 1.1 that the families at the Bottom 90%
of the income distribution did not benefit at all from the changes in
taxes, regulations, and international finance and trade that occurred from
1973 through 2012. While the average real income of this group rose
dramatically from 1933 through 1973, increasing by a factor of 5, it trended
downward from 1973 through the 1980s and didn't start to trend upward again
until 1993. This upward trend was short lived, however, as the real income
for the Bottom 90% began to decrease again after 2000.
The average real income of the Bottom 90% of the income distribution
actually fell by 13% during the 39 year period from 1973 through 2012. This
13% decrease provides a stark contrast to the 368% increase in real income
this group experienced in the 39-year period that proceeded 1973. In
absolute terms, the average real income of the bottom 90% increased by
$27,985 from 1934 through 1973 and fell by $4,587 from 1973 through 2012.
The $30,997 average income the bottom 90% received in 2012 was actually less
than the $31,006 average this income group received 46years earlier in 1966.
The fall in average real income from 1973 through 2012 received by the
Bottom 90% of the income distribution is particularly stark in light of
the
104% increase in the productivity of labor
that took place in the economy during this period. None of the benefits
of this increase in productivity of labor went to the bottom 90% of the
income distribution. (Saez
Gordon
Sum)
As is indicated in Figure 1.2, the situation was somewhat better for
families in the Top 90-95% of the income distribution. In 2012, this
group consisted of the 8.0 million families that received an income between
$113,820 and $161,438. The 2012 average income for this group was $133,530.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
Like the Bottom 90%, the average real income of Top 90-95%
rose dramatically from 1933 through 1973, increasing by a factor of 3.75.
After 1973, its average income leveled off but began an upward trend in 1982
that peaked in 2000 and again in 2007. It then receded somewhat by 2012.
While the average real income of the Top 90-95% of the population did
increase by 25% from 1973 through 2012, this increase for that 39-year
period was a mere fraction of the 251% increase this group experienced
during the 39 years that proceeded 1973 and a third ($26,704) of the $76,375
increase this group received in absolute terms during that 39-year period.
The pattern in Figure 1.2 repeats itself in Figure 1.3 for the
Top 95-99% of the income distribution. This group consisted of 6.4
million families that received between $161,438 and $393,941 in 2012 with an
average income of $226,405. The 44% increase in real income this group
received during the 39-year period following 1973 was, again, far less than
the 187% increase that took place during the 39-year period before 1973 and
only 68% ($69,669) of the $102,127 increase it had received in absolute
terms during that period.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
It's not until we get to the top 1% of the income distribution that this
pattern changes, though not everyone in this group benefited equally.
Figure 1.4 shows the average income of the Top 99.0-99.5% of the
income distribution. In 2012, this group consisted of 803,405 families that
received between $393,941 and $611,805 with an average income of $477,738.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
The average real income of this income group increased by 74% during the
39-year period from 1973 through 2012. This was a significant improvement
over lower-income groups. Even though this is less than half of the 165%
increase this group received in the 40-year period preceding 1973, the
$203,097 increase in real income that took place from 1973 through 2012 is
at least greater than the $171,155 increase in real income this group
received from 1934 through 1973.
It's not until we get to the top 1/2 of the top 1% that we come to the first
income group that unambiguously benefited from the changes in tax,
deregulatory, and international policies that have taken place during the
past forty years. Figure 1.5 through Figure 1.7 break down the
top half of the top1% of the income distribution into three Groups:
Figure 1.5 shows the average income of the Top
99.5-99.9% of the income distribution. In 2012, this group consisted of
642,724 families that received incomes between $611,805 and $1,906,047 with
an average income of $969,544.
Figure 1.6 shows the average income of the Top
99.9-99.99% of the income distribution. In 2012, this group consisted of
80,341 families that received incomes between $1,906,047 and $10,256,235
with an average income of $3,661,347.
Figure 1.7 shows the average income of the Top 0.01%
of the income distribution. In 2012, this group consisted of 16,068 families
with incomes equal to or above $10,256,235 with an average income of
$30,785,699.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
Here are the true beneficiaries of the changes in tax, deregulation, and
international trade policies over the past forty years. While the average
real income of the bottom 90% of the population fell from $36 thousand a
year in 1973 to $31 thousand a year in 2012, the average real income of the
top 0.5% of the population more than tripled:
For the Top 99.5-99.9% it went from $426 thousand to
$970 thousand a year, a $544 thousand increase compared to a $231 thousand
increase from 1934 through 1973.
For the Top 99.9-99.99% it went from $971 thousand to
$3.7 million a year, a $2.7 million increase compared to a $402 thousand
increase from 1934 through 1973.
And for the Top .01% it went from $4.5 million to $30.8
million a year, a $26.3 million increase compared to a $1.9 million increase
from 1934 through 1973, all measured in 2012 dollars.
The relative magnitudes of the numbers involved can be seen in Figure 1.8
which plots the average incomes of the various income groups from 1913
through 2012 on the same scale.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
This is what the changes in tax, regulatory, and international finance and
trade policies in the name of economic efficiency over the past forty years
have led to. Namely, a huge windfall for the upper 1% of the income
distribution, a net loss for the Bottom 90% of the income
distribution, and relatively little if anything for the 90-99% of the income
distribution in between. (Piketty
Saez
Gordon
Sum) What's more, the situation is even worse
for those families at the Bottom 90% than the above numbers indicate.
The average income of the Bottom 90% would have fallen even further
than the 13% indicated in Figure 1.1 were it not for the fact that
the percentage of women who participate in the labor force has increased
over
30% since 1973. This suggests that the number
of two income families in the Bottom 90% has increased significantly
during this period as mothers were forced to leave their children to the
care of others and enter the labor force in order to maintain their family's
standard of living. When this is combined with a more regressive tax
structure—higher payroll taxes, excise taxes, fines and fees, and higher
tuition at public colleges and universities—it is clear that the 90% of the
population at the bottom of the income distribution is significantly worse
off today than it was forty years ago. (NYT
Charts)
In attempting to understand how and why the above changes in income came
about, it is instructive to examine the way in which the changes in our tax,
regulatory, and international policies have affected our economic, social,
and political systems. The place to begin is with the effects on these
systems that followed the
Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980
and
Garn–St. Germain Depository Institutions Ac
of 1982. These two acts 1) lessened the
reserve requirements of banks, 2) provided mechanisms to assist failing
banks rather than closing them down, 3) phased out interest rate ceilings on
bank deposits, and 4) expanded the kinds of loans
thrifts (savings
and loans and
savings banks) could make so as to allow them
to become more competitive with the
commercial banks. (FDIC
Garcia) It was hoped these changes would
enhance the level of competition in the financial markets and improve
economic efficiency. This is not exactly how this grand experiment in
deregulation worked out.
The early 1980s was a particularly ominous time to deregulate the savings
and loans. At the end of the 1981 recession, 10% of the savings and loans
were
insolvent on an accounting basis, and
institutions that had no
tangible equity at all controlled 35% of the
industry's assets. (Black
FDIC) These savings and loans—with their
federally insured deposits—were allowed to compete on an equal footing with
the rest of the financial system in spite of the fact that insolvent
financial institutions have nothing to lose by rolling the dice and betting
the farm on high stakes investments in trying to recoup their losses. After
all, if they win they keep it all. If they lose they just increase their
insolvency, and since they were bankrupt to start with, they are no worse
off than they were before; their investors and taxpayers (because of the
government’s obligations to insured depositors) take the increased losses,
not the owners or managers of insolvent savings and loans. (Garcia)
What's more, the reduced regulation and supervision created innumerable
opportunities to exploit the system through fraud. As a result, the
character of the savings and loan industry changed after deregulation as a
new breed of owners, such as
Charles H. Keating and
Hal Greenwood Jr., began to shift out of home
mortgages and into commercial real-estate loans, direct investments in
real-estate projects, junk bonds and other securities, and innumerable other
risky areas where the potential for fraud abounds—areas they had been barred
from entering since the 1930s as a result of the lessons learned from the
1920s. (FDIC
Black
Akerlof
Stewart
Garcia)
There was a virtual explosion in
Acquisition, Development, and Construction
(ADC) loans issued by savings and loans following deregulation whereby
real-estate developers were allowed to borrow money for projects with no
interest or principal payments for three years. The savings and loans added
huge fees to these loans which they booked as income in the year the loans
were made. The interest was also booked as income as it accrued over the
three years of the loan even though no interest was actually paid. This led,
through the magic of accounting, to huge paper profits out of which the
owners and managers of the savings and loans paid themselves huge dividends,
salaries, and bonuses in real cash even though no cash had been received for
fees or interest owed.
What happened when the loans came due and the developers couldn't pay? No
problem! The savings and loans just refinanced the loans, added more fees
and interest to the principal, booked more paper fee and interest income,
and paid themselves more dividends, salaries, and bonuses in real cash. And
they were allowed to finance all of this through brokered deposits—federally
insured certificates of deposit that were sold by brokerage firms, such as
Merrill Lynch, to investors all over the
country. The money from federally insured brokered deposits allowed the
savings and loans to expand their deposit base, expand their ADC loans,
finance innumerable other fraudulent schemes, increase their paper profits,
and to come up with the real cash necessary to finance the huge payments of
dividends, salaries, and bonuses that the managers and owners took out of
these institutions. (Black
Akerlof
Stewart
FDIC)
While this was going on, the inflow of credit into a number of regional
commercial real-estate markets that accompanied this expansion of savings
and loan activity, mostly in the Southwest and Northeast, started
speculative booms in these markets. As the
speculative bubbles in these markets developed
the fraudulently managed institutions began to threaten the honestly managed
institutions—not just among the savings and loans but among the savings and
commercial banks as well. Fraudulently managed savings and loans bid
fiercely for brokered deposits as they bid up the rates paid on these
deposits. This, in turn, increased costs in the entire financial system as
the fraudulently managed savings and loans dug the hole deeper for everyone.
Honestly managed institutions that were forced to, or were naively willing
to invest in the booming commercial real-estate markets made the situation
worse as the
speculative bubbles in these markets grew.
ADC scams were not the only savings and loan scams that followed in the wake
of the financial deregulation of the early 1980s. Deregulation made it
possible for
Michael Milken and other
corporate raiders of the 1980s to finance
their leveraged buyouts and hostile takeovers by funneling the junk bonds
they issued into captive savings and loans. The
corporate raiders used the assets of the
target companies as collateral for the junk bonds they issued. The proceeds
from the sale of those bonds were then used not only to pay off the existing
stockholders but to pay huge dividends and bonuses to the raiders themselves
as they drove the companies they took over deeper and deeper into debt. (Black
Stewart)
As the
speculative bubbles in the markets fueled by
ADC scams burst and the companies taken over in junk bond scams began to go
bankrupt toward the end of the 1980s and into the 1990s, the result was the
first major financial crisis in the United States since the
Great Depression. (FDIC)
Some 1,300 savings institutions failed, along with 1,600 commercial banks.
That amounted to almost a third of all savings institutions along with 10%
of all commercial banks in existence at the time. By comparison, only
243 banks failed from 1934 through 1980. It
cost the American taxpayer
$130 billion to reimburse the depositors in
the failed institutions, and the near meltdown of the financial system that
resulted was a precursor to the
1990-1991 recession. (Black
FDIC
Krugman
Akerlof
Stewart) In the end, the corporate raiders and
the owners and managers of the savings and loans walked away with billions;
taxpayers took the losses.
While the number of depository institutions that failed during this crisis
was only a third of the number that failed during the
Great Depression, the extraordinary nature of
the
Savings and Loan Crisis is indicated by the
graph constructed by the
FDIC displayed in Figure 1.9.
Source:
FDIC
This chart shows the number of FDIC insured commercial and savings banks
that failed each year from 1934 through 1995. While it includes only the
1,600 FDIC insured institutions that failed and does not include the
1,300 failed savings and loans insured by the
FSLIC,
it clearly indicates the degree of stability in the system from the end of
World War II through the 1970s before the era of deregulation began in
earnest, and the degree to which deregulation in the 1980s destabilized the
system.
Those who were responsible
for deregulating the financial system during the 1980s were, of course,
shocked, shocked to find that their actions had led to a massive
outbreak of fraud, but this outbreak was to be expected. After all, the main
function of government is to enact and enforce the law. This
fundamental governmental function cannot be performed in a fair or just
or efficient manner by private enterprise guided by the profit motive. It
can only be performed in a fair and just and efficient manner by a
democratically elected government that is dedicated to this end, and the way
in which a democratically elected government that is dedicated to this end
enacts and enforces the laws against fraud in the financial system is
through the regulation and supervision of financial institutions. It should
be no surprise that reducing the regulation and supervision of financial
institutions led to an increase in fraud perpetrated by those in charge of
these institutions. This is especially so in light
of the tax cuts of the 1980s which reduced the top marginal tax rate from
70% in 1980 to
28% by 1988. These lower tax rates on
ultra high incomes made it possible for massive fortunes to be made through
fraud within these institutions.
While there was an attempt by Congress to
reregulate the financial markets in the late 1980s and early 1990s, and
taxes were raised somewhat during the late Bush I and early Clinton
administrations, (TF
TAP) the cat was out of the bag. The fortunes
made by those who looted the savings and loans during the 1980s clearly
demonstrated how lower tax rates on ultra high incomes combined with a lack
of oversight on the part of government regulators made it possible for
fortunes to be made by those willing to bend or ignore the law. Even though
over a thousand individuals associated with the savings and loan debacle
were convicted of felonies, many, if not most were able to walk away with
their fortunes intact. (Black
Akerlof
Stewart) This was the lesson learned by those
at the top of the economic food chain, and this same lesson was drawn from
the experiences in other industries as well. (Frontline
MSN)
With so much after-tax money involved, the lack of government regulation
allowed the entire fiduciary structure of our economic system to become
corrupted. Throughout the 1980s and 1990s stockholders lost control of
corporations as the corporate governance structure broke down. Boards of
directors became vassals of their CEOs, and management salaries and bonuses
soared to astronomical levels. Accounting firms found they could make more
money advising corporations how to make paper profits in order to justify
increases in management salaries and bonuses than they could by providing
independent audits of companies' books for stockholders. Brokerage firms
found they could make more money hyping worthless mutual funds and internet,
energy, and telecom stocks than they could by providing sound investment
advice to their clients. Investment banks found it more profitable to
dissolve their partnerships, become corporations, and speculate for their
own account with investors' money than to provide underwriting and advisory
services to their clients. (Bogle
Galbraith
Stewart
Baker
Kuttner
Phillips)
All of this
involved huge conflicts of interest
between corporation and mutual fund managers and the shareholders these
managers are supposed to serve, between accounting firms and the investing
public accounting firms are supposed to serve, between brokerage firms and
the investors brokerage firms are supposed to serve, and between investment
banks and the corporations investment banks are supposed to serve. These
conflicts of interest contributed directly to the
Drexel Burnham Lambert,
Charles Keating,
Michael Milken,
Ivan Boesky, and other
insider trading,
junk bond, and
Savings and Loan frauds that were a direct
cause of the
junk bond and
commercial real estate bubbles of the 1980s,
the bursting of which was a precursor to the
1990-1991 recession. They also contributed
directly to the
HomeStore/AOL,
Enron,
Global Crossing, and
WorldCom frauds that were a direct cause of
the
dotcom and
telecom bubbles of the 1990s, the bursting of
which led to the
2001 recession.
In addition, usury laws were repealed throughout the country, and credit
card companies were allowed to charge exorbitant interest rates, exact
unreasonable fees, and to manipulate payment dates and the dates at which
payments were recorded to force customers to pay late charges even though
payments were mailed and received on time. (PRIG)
At the same time, credit card companies devised elaborate schemes to lure
naive and financially unsophisticated customers deeper and deeper into
debt. And in 2005 the
Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act was passed which
made it almost impossible for lower income people to discharge their credit
card and other debts in bankruptcy. (Frontline
MSN
Warren
Tabb
Morgan
Scott)
Antitrust laws were ignored throughout this entire period as corporations
were allowed to merge into mega institutions with overwhelming economic and
political power. Laws against interstate banking
were repealed in 1994, and as the banking
industry began to concentrate its power, two legislative acts removed key
regulatory constraints on the financial system. The first was the
Financial Services Modernization Act of 1999 (FSMA)
which repealed the prohibition against commercial
bank holding companies becoming conglomerates
that provide both
commercial and
investment banking services along with
insurance and brokerage services. The second was the
Commodity Futures Modernization Act (CFMA) of
2000 which blocked attempts to regulate the
derivatives markets.
These changes made it possible to accumulate wealth in the 1980s, 1990s, and
2000s at levels that were heretofore unimaginable. Along with that wealth
came unimaginable levels of economic and political power. Along with that
power came a virtual collapse of integrity in our financial and political
systems. In the wake of the
dotcom and
telecom bubbles bursting and the collapse of
the
HomeStore/AOL,
Enron,
Global Crossing, and
WorldCom frauds, the mega banks and accounting
firms that had facilitated these frauds found they could make hundreds of
billions of dollars by
securitizing
subprime mortgages,
that is, by securitizing mortgages executed by borrowers who did not qualify
for
prime rate loans. This discovery set in motion
a set of forces that drove our economic system—along with that of the entire
world—headlong into a catastrophe of epic proportions.
Securitizing subprime mortgages became so
profitable that by the early 2000s there were not enough qualified subprime
borrowers to meet the demands of securitizers. Rather than cut back their
operations, predatory mortgage originators (such as
Washington Mutual,
Countrywide,
IndyMac,
New Century,
Fremont Investment & Loan, and
CitiFinancial) talked millions of naive people
into applying for subprime mortgages by misrepresenting the nature of these
mortgages. The most serious misrepresentation was to offer borrowers an
adjustable rate mortgage (ARM) with an
unreasonably low
teaser rate without explaining the effect on
their monthly payment when the initial rate adjusted to the actual rate.
Using this and other ploys, borrowers who qualified for modest subprime
mortgages at reasonable subprime rates were talked into applying for
adjustable-rate subprime mortgages with teaser rates that would reset in two
or three years to rates they could not afford. Even borrowers who qualified
for modest prime rate mortgages at reasonable prime rates were talked into
applying for exorbitant subprime mortgages they could not afford when the
rates reset. (Senate
FCIC
WSFC
Spitzer)
Securitizers also turned to
Alt-A borrowers, that is, borrowers who were able to secure mortgage
loans with little or no verification of the asset,
income, and employment status they reported on the applications for these
loans. These
no-doc loans, as they were called in the
beginning, were soon to become known as
NINJA loans—short for No Income, No Job, and
no Assets—or just plain
liar loans. At this point
borrowers not qualified for any kind of mortgage
at all were approved for mortgages, and real-estate speculators got into the
act.
As housing prices rose, speculators discovered they could obtain
Alt-A mortgages with little or no money down.
As a result, a host of speculators took out
Alt-A mortgages knowing that if the prices of
their properties increased they would profit greatly, and if the prices of
their properties went down they could walk away from these mortgages with
little or no loss to themselves. When such financing was combined with
fraudulently obtained appraisals, many speculators were able to walk away
from their loans with a profit without making a single payment on their
mortgage. (T2P
Senate
FCIC
WSFC)
Next, in order to sell these mortgages it was necessary for mortgage
originators to obtain appraisals of the underlying properties consistent
with the values of the mortgages being originated. To obtain these
appraisals, mortgage originators shopped around for appraisers who would
write consistent appraisals and shunned appraisers who would not. This
guaranteed rising incomes for appraisers who cooperated with the mortgage
originators and falling incomes for those who did not. At the same time,
some lenders set up in-house mortgage appraisal subsidiaries so as to
guarantee the kinds of appraisals they wanted. The result was a systematic
upward bias in real-estate appraisals, and, as the flow of funds into the
real-estate sector increased, this led to a systematic upward bias in
housing prices. (FCIC
WSFC
Mian)
Firms that securitize mortgages were the next link in the financial food
chain that fed off the subprime and Alt-A mortgages. In order for investment
banks and other firms that securitized mortgages to sell their
Mortgage-Backed Securities (MBSs)
at the highest possible price, they had to receive the highest possible
rating from a
bond rating agency. To accomplish this, the
securitizers followed the lead of the mortgage originators to steer their
business to bond rating agencies that gave them the highest ratings and away
from those that gave them lower ratings. In this way the companies that
securitized mortgages were able to get the three major bond rating agencies
(Moody’s,
Standard and Poor’s, and
Fitch) to give
triple-A
ratings to
Mortgage-Backed Securities even though the
rating agencies had no creditable basis on which to rate these securities.
(House
FCIC
WSFC)
From 2002 through 2007 literally millions of fraudulent obtained subprime
and Alt-A mortgages provided the collateral for trillions of dollars of
Mortgage-Backed Securities (MBSs) that were
spread throughout the financial system of the entire world—as well as into
banks, insurance companies, pension funds, money market funds, mutual funds,
and institutional endowment funds at home. (T2P
FCIC
WSFC) In the meantime, hundreds of billions of
dollars were paid out in salaries, bonuses, and dividends to those who
participated in this fraudulent securitization process. Even the managers of
the banks, insurance companies, and mutual and endowment funds that bought
these toxic assets—and whose constituents eventually suffered losses as a
result—were paid billions of dollars in real cash as their paper profits
grew along with the
housing bubble that had been facilitated by this fraud.
Huge fortunes were amassed as this process grew beyond all bounds of reason,
and as the fraud grew in the subprime and Alt-A mortgage markets, the
officials in control of the federal government during the Bush II
administration did nothing to stop it. When state and local authorities
complained to the federal government about the predatory lending practices
in their communities, not only did the
Federal Reserve—which had the absolute
authority under the
Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act
(HOEPA) to stop these practices (Natter
WSFC)—do nothing to clamp down on the
predatory practices in the mortgage market, the Justice Department actually
went to court to keep state and local authorities from regulating this
market. (Spitzer
FCIC
WSFC) As a result, no restraints were placed
on the fraud being perpetrated by the mortgage originators, securitizers,
and bond rating agencies as the entire securitization process became
corrupt.
The resulting
housing bubble grew dramatically in the mid
2000s, and, as with all
speculative bubbles, it was only a matter of
time before it burst. By the time it did,
$11 trillion worth of mortgages on residential
properties with inflated prices were created that could not sustain their
value. To make things worse, virtually all of the worst-of-the-worst
mortgages—the fraudulently obtained subprime and Alt-A mortgages—were
bundled into
Mortgage-Backed Securities (MBSs) and sold all
over the world, and over half of the triple-A rated MBSs ended up on the
books of our own financial institutions—on the books of investment and
commercial banks, money market funds, mutual funds, pension funds, endowment
funds, and insurance companies throughout the country. (NYU)
As housing prices began to fall in 2006, the
Mortgage-Backed Securities (MBSs) that were
created while housing prices were driven up to unsustainable levels began to
lose their value. The ensuing panic drove all of the major investment banks
in our country (and many of the commercial banks as well) into insolvency.
The Federal Reserve was forced to increased
Reserve Bank Credit by over
a trillion dollars before the resulting run on
the financial system came to an end, and the federal government was forced
to put up
$700 billion in the
Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) funds to
keep the financial system from collapsing. In the meantime, the unemployment
rate hit
10% in October of 2009; trillions of dollars
in the wealth of homeowners, insurance companies, mutual funds, pension
funds, and in 401(k)s evaporated, and the financial and international
exchange systems of the entire world were destabilized as a worldwide
economic crisis followed in the wake of this disaster. (Stiglitz
NYU
FCIC
WSFC)
The securitization of fraudulently obtained subprime and Alt-A mortgages in
the early to mid 2000s was, undoubtedly,
the greatest fraud in history, one that sent
shockwaves throughout the entire world. Those who bought homes during the
housing bubble facilitated by this fraud, whose pension plans were invested
in the
toxic assets created as a result of this
bubble, who had a stake in the endowment and mutual funds that invested in
these assets, the small investors with 401 (k)s, those who depended on wages
and salaries for their livelihood and
found themselves unemployed as a result of the
economic collapse caused by the bursting of the housing bubble, and those
who lost their homes as a result of the collapsing housing market and the
recession that followed were particularly hard hit by the economic
catastrophe that followed in the wake of this fraud. At the same time those
who stood at the center of this fraud made fortunes. (Galbraith
FCIC
WSFC)
The same is true of the economic disasters that followed the hostile
takeover/leverage buyout craze and the
savings and loan fiasco of the 1980s and the
dotcom and
telecom bubbles of the late 1990s. Huge
profits, bonuses, and windfall gains were generated as asset prices were bid
up in the process of creating these
speculative bubbles, and all of these bubbles
were precursors to economic catastrophes. (Stewart
FCIC
WSFC
Mian) The extent to which this is so is shown
in Figure 1.10 through Figure 1.12.
Figure 1.10
provides a breakdown of the share of total income that went to the top
10% of the income distribution from 1913 through 2010. This graph shows
the relative stability of the share of total income of the top 90-99% of the
income distribution since1945 compared to that of the Top 1%. It also
shows the volatility of the share of total income that went to the Top 1%
before 1945 and after 1980 compared to the relative stability of the
share this group received in the period of restrictive financial regulation
from 1945 to 1980. Of particular interest is the way in which the volatility
of the Top 1% is tied to speculative bubbles.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
The extent to which the Top 1% of the income distribution benefited
from these bubbles is clearly shown in Figure 1.10 by
the 53% increase in income share (including
capital gains) this group received during the
1921-1926 real estate and the
1926-1929 stock market bubbles that led up to the
Great Crash of 1929 and the
Great Depression of the 1930s,
the 55% increase in income share this group
received during the 1981-1988
junk bond and
commercial real estate bubbles of the 1980s that led up to
Savings and Loan Crisis and the
1990-1991 recession,
the 51% increase in income share this group
received during the 1994-2000
dotcom and
telecom bubbles that led up to the
stock market crash of 2000 and the
2001 recession, and
the 39% increase in income share this group
received during the
2002-2007 housing bubble that led up to the Crash of 2008 and the
worldwide economic crisis that followed.
Similarly, Figure 1.11 shows the amount of income received in the
form of capital gains as a percent of total income from 1916 through 2012.
This figure displays a pattern similar to that in Figure 1.10 with
relatively little volatility in the percent of total income received in the
form of capital gains during the period of restrictive financial regulation
from 1945 to 1980 compared to the preceding and following periods. While the
1986 spike in this graph conflates the effects of the
anticipated 1987 increase in the capital gains tax
with the effects of the
junk bond and
commercial real estate bubbles of the 1980s,
there were no capital gains tax increases in the 1920s, 1990s, or 2000s.
Source:
The World Top Incomes Database.
The increase in capital gains by fully 6% of total income in the 1920s,
1990s, and 2000s depicted in Figure 1.11 clearly shows the effects of
speculation on income during these eras that led to economic catastrophes as
those who profited from these bubbles realized huge capital gains—and it is
worth emphasizing here that these are realized capital gains. When
the crash came there was someone or some institution on the other side of
the sale that generated these realized capital gains that realized the loss
including pension funds, insurance companies, 401(k)s, endowment funds, and
taxpayers when depositors and financial institutions were bailed out.
While Figure 1.10 and Figure 1.11 deal with household and
family incomes, Figure 1.12 shows how the financial system fared
through the
housing bubble of the 2000s.
Source:
Bureau of Economic Analysis (6.17D
1.1.5
1.5.4).
Of particular interest in Figure 1.12 is the 173% increase in
Private Sector Financial Profits from 1998 to 2005 following
passage of the
Financial Services Modernization Act of 1999
(FSMA) and the
Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000
(CFMA). These two acts, combined with the refusal by the Bush II
administration and the Greenspan Federal Reserve to enforce what little
financial regulation remained, gave the non-depository financial
institutions a free hand to do just about whatever they wanted to do in the
world of finance. What they wanted to do was securitize millions of
fraudulently obtained subprime and Alt-A mortgages and sell those mortgages
all over the world. In the process they managed to accumulate over $700
billion dollars in profits from 2001 through 2007 in excess of what they
would have made if there had been no
housing bubble and their profits had stayed at
their 1998 level. And it is worth noting here that in 1998 we were in the
midst of the
dotcom and
telecom bubbles, and financial profits were
already at a
record high.
Deregulation of the financial markets was done in the name of economic
efficiency, but the massive fortunes made in the process of creating the
dotcom,
telecom, and
housing bubbles had nothing to do with
economic efficiency. Nor were there economic efficiencies gained in the
fortunes made in the
junk bond and
commercial real estate bubbles created during
the savings and loan fiasco or in the
leverage buyout/hostile takeover craze of the
1980s. These fortunes were amassed in the process of squandering our
economic resources on a massive scale as companies were driven dangerously
into debt through leveraged buyouts and hostile takeovers or in attempting
to avoid such takeovers; funds were directed into sham internet companies,
and resources were directed into the production of redundant telecom
facilities and innumerable real-estate projects that sat empty as the
bubbles burst and millions of people lost their jobs, their homes, their
pensions, their life savings, and their hopes and dreams for the future in
the wake of the economic catastrophes that followed.
Economic efficiency means maximizing the amount of output produced with
given amounts of resources toward the end of improving human well-being.
It’s not about
transferring income and wealth from the bottom of the income distribution to
the top. This transfer of income and wealth
may seem efficient from the perspective of
those at the top. It is clearly not efficient
from the perspective of the vast majority of the population at the bottom.
The suggestion that the policy changes that have occurred over the past
forty years—policy changes that led to a collapse of the fiduciary structure
of society, gave rise to massive frauds, generated massive rewards for those
who perpetrated these frauds, and
harmed the vast majority of the population to
the benefit of the few—have somehow improved the economic efficiency of the
American economy is absurd.
Over 8 million people had lost their jobs by 2010 as a result of the
housing bubble bursting in 2006, and 4 million
families lost their homes. In 2010, another 4.5 million families were
seriously behind in their mortgage payment or in the process of foreclosure.
“In the fall of 2010, 1 in every 11 outstanding residential mortgage loans
in the United States was at least one payment past due but not yet in
foreclosure.” Nationwide, 10.8 million families—22.5% of all families with
mortgages—owed more on their mortgages in 2010 than their houses were worth.
In Florida, Michigan, and Nevada more than 50% of all mortgages were
underwater, and it is projected that by the time this crisis is over as many
as 13 million families could lose their homes. (FCIC)
These numbers are the end result of the economic policy changes we have made
over the past forty years, and there’s nothing efficient about them.
This book is available in Kindle and paperback format
at Amazon.com for a nominal contribution to this website.
Amazon.com
Where Did All The Money Go?
How Lower Taxes, Less Government, and Deregulation Redistribute Income and
Create Economic Instability
Amazon.com
Table
of Contents
Prologue
Chapter 1: Income, Fraud, Instability, and Efficiency
Changes in the Distribution of Income
The Savings and Loan Debacle
The Rise of Predatory Finance and Corruption
Securitization and the Crash of 2008
Speculative Bubbles and Economic Efficiency
Chapter 2: International Finance and Trade
International Crises and Financial Bailouts
The Overvalued Dollar and International Trade
The Overvalued Dollar and International Debt
Why Foreign Debt Matters
Appendix on International Exchange
Chapter 3: Mass Production, Income, Exports, and Debt
Exports and Imports
100 Years of Income and Debt
Why the System Collapsed
Appendix on Estimating Debt
Chapter 4: Going Into Debt
Debt and Deregulation
What Financial Institutions Do
Those Who Cannot Remember the Past
The Fall and Rise of Ideology
Chapter 5: Nineteenth Century Financial Crises
First and Second Banks of the U. S.
National Banking Acts of 1863 and 1864
Solvency, Liquidity, and Banks
The Uniqueness of Banks
Leverage, Profits, and Risk
Failings of the National Banking System
Chapter 6: The Federal Reserve and Financial Regulation
Controlling the Amount of Currency
Controlling Loans and Deposits
Roaring Twenties and Great Depression
The Dynamics of Financial Instability
Reforming the System
Chapter 7: Rise of the Shadow Banking System
Financial Innovation in the 1970s
Importance of Collateralization
The Shadow Banking System
Appendix on Financial Markets and Instruments
Chapter 8: Mortgages, Derivatives, and Leverage
The Mortgage Market
Derivatives and Leverage
Credit Default Swaps and Synthetic CDOs
Shadow Banks, Derivatives, and Systemic Risk
Chapter 9: LTCM and the Panic of 1998
Rise of LTCM
Fall of LTCM
Bailout of LTCM
What Went Wrong
Lessons Not Learned
Chapter 10: The Crash of 2008
The Gathering Storm
The Panic Begins
How We Survived
Looking Forward
Chapter 11: Lessons from the Great Depression
Purging Debt in the 1930s
Monetary Policy, 1929-1933
Fiscal Policy, 1929-1933
What We Should have Learned
Chapter 12: Coming to Grips with Reality
Lower Taxes, Less Government, and Deregulation
On The Need to Raise Taxes
Reregulating the Financial System
Reregulating International Exchange
Reregulating Collective Bargaining
Deleveraging Non-Federal Debt
Summary and Conclusion
Acknowledgments
Annotated Bibliography
End Notes
End Notes
The reason for the stability from the
end of World War II through the 1970s and why this changed in the 1980s
is examined in detail in Chapter 5 through Chapter 7 below.
The reasons for the need to regulate the
markets for derivatives are examined in detail in Chapter 8.
In a case study of
Moody’s Investors Service the
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission’s Report concluded:
The three credit rating agencies were key enablers of
the financial meltdown. The mortgage-related securities at the heart of
the crisis could not have been marketed and sold without their seal of
approval. Investors re- lied on them, often blindly. In some cases, they
were obligated to use them, or regulatory capital standards were hinged
on them. This crisis could not have happened without the rating
agencies. Their ratings helped the market soar and their down- grades
through 2007 and 2008 wreaked havoc across markets and firms.
From 2000 to 2007, Moody’s rated nearly 45,000
mortgage-related securities as triple-A. This compares with six
private-sector companies in the United States that carried this coveted
rating in early 2010. In 2006 alone, Moody’s put its triple-A stamp of
approval on 30 mortgage-related securities every working day. The
results were disastrous: 83% of the mortgage securities rated triple-A
that year ultimately were downgraded.
You will also read about the forces at work behind the
breakdowns at Moody’s, including the flawed computer models, the
pressure from financial firms that paid for the ratings, the relentless
drive for market share, the lack of resources to do the job despite
record profits, and the absence of meaningful public oversight. And you
will see that without the active participation of the rating agencies,
the market for mort-gage-related securities could not have been what it
became.